Distortion Factors, Prices of Imported Intermediate Inputs, and Total Factor Productivity: Ex Post Accounting Method Based on General Equilibrium Modelling of the Noncompetitive Input-Output Network Structure
NI Hongfu
Institute of Economics/University of Chinese Academy of Social Sciences, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences
Summary:
China's economic development since the reform and opening-up in 1978 is remarkable. However, the growth of China's economic development shows slowing trends over the past decade because of the triple pressure of shrinking demand, supply shocks, and weakening expectations. Following the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic, changes have accelerated and China's external environment is now more complex, severe, and uncertain. How to interpret China's economic growth over the past 40 years and the changes in total factor productivity (TFP) and its driving factors? Answering these questions is of great practical significance. Many studies explore TFP. For example, macro-level studies are generally based on the classical Solow residual method to estimate TFP. In these studies, any unobservable factors affecting economic growth can be attributed to TFP; therefore, the classical Solow residual is like a “black box.” It is impossible to accurately understand the determinants of TFP theoretically; thus, there are misunderstandings in the understanding of TFP, which also leads to differences in understanding changes in TFP. Studies of the decomposition of TFP in China lack a unified theoretical model and especially a general equilibrium model of the input-output network structure. Based on the basic framework of Baqaee and Farhi (2020), this paper constructs a general equilibrium model of a noncompetitive input-output network structure with imported intermediate inputs and distortion factors suitable for China's characteristics. The paper then proposes a new method for calculating and decomposing total productivity, which empirically calculates and decomposes changes in TFP. This paper makes two marginal contributions to the literature. First, the theoretical model of the production network structure is expanded. The general Baqaee and Farhi (2020) model is based on the general equilibrium framework of a production network structure with markup. In addition to the markup caused by monopoly power, the structure of China's tax system with indirect tax as the main body obviously differs from that of the United States with direct tax as the main body. Therefore, building a general equilibrium model for a production network structure that considers the impact mechanism of indirect tax is more in line with China's reality. Second, this paper enriches methods for calculating and decomposing TFP. Under the general equilibrium framework, this paper derives a new unified measurement framework for economic growth accounting and TFP decomposition, considers the impact mechanism of terms of trade, and expands the decomposition method for TFP. The results show that capital and TFP are the main sources of China's economic growth and that there is an obvious “see-saw” between the two, but the contribution of labor is relatively small and the rate of contribution shows a downward trend. The change to pure technical efficiency is the main contributor to changes in TFP; however, it shows a downward trend and 2007 is a watershed year. Following the gradual loss of the late development advantage of technology imitation, the speed of technological progress also shows a gradual decline since 2007. After 2012, however, China's pure technical efficiency improves gradually under the influence of the innovation-driven development strategy. The contribution of the change in distortion factor allocation efficiency for TFP changes from positive to negative, while the contribution of the change in the terms of trade for imported intermediate products to TFP changes from negative to positive. Against the background of the establishment of a socialist market economic system and China's entry into the World Trade Organization, the change in resource allocation efficiency promotes TFP. From 2007 to 2012, however, following the global financial crisis and China's “four-trillion investment plan,” distortion factor allocation efficiency deteriorated in the short term and pulled down TFP, but its negative impact decreased after 2012. The following three conclusions are based on these results. First, TFP is not only the main source of improving China's economic growth in the future but also the key to achieving high-quality development. Following the decline in the return on capital caused by the decreasing scale of marginal returns and resource and environmental constraints, it will be difficult to sustain large-scale investments in the future and the contribution of capital to economic growth will decline. Second, the technological progress brought by independent innovation in the future is the main source of TFP improvement. Third, improving the efficiency of resource allocation is still an important source for improving TFP and achieving high-quality development. The practical experience of China's reform and opening-up confirms the important role of improving technical and factor allocation efficiency in rapid economic growth.
倪红福. 扭曲因子、进口中间品价格与全要素生产率——基于非竞争型投入产出网络结构一般均衡模型事后核算方法[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 500(2): 21-39.
NI Hongfu. Distortion Factors, Prices of Imported Intermediate Inputs, and Total Factor Productivity: Ex Post Accounting Method Based on General Equilibrium Modelling of the Noncompetitive Input-Output Network Structure. Journal of Financial Research, 2022, 500(2): 21-39.
[1]程名望、贾晓佳和仇焕广,2019,《中国经济增长(1978—2015):灵感还是汗水?》,《经济研究》第7期,第30~45页。 [2]陈昌兵,2014,《可变折旧率估计及资本存量测算》,《经济研究》第12期,第72~85页。 [3]高凌云和王洛林,2010,《进口贸易与工业行业全要素生产率》,《经济学(季刊)》第2期,第391~414页。 [4]黄满盈和邓晓虹,2009,《贸易条件变动对中国经济增长影响的实证分析》,《商业经济与管理》第 10期,第46~52页。 [5]倪红福,2018,《全球价值链人民币实际有效汇率:理论、测度及结构解析》,《管理世界》第7期,第50~69页。 [6]倪红福、龚六堂和夏杰长,2018,《什么削弱了中国出口价格竞争力?——基于全球价值链分行业实际有效汇率新方法》,《经济学(季刊)》第1期,第367~392页。 [7]倪红福,2021,《生产网络结构、减税降费和福利效应》,《世界经济》第1期,第25~53页。 [8]倪红福和闫冰倩,2021,《减税降费的价格和福利效应——引入成本传导率的投入产出价格模型分析》,《金融研究》第2期,第35~88页。 [9]倪红福、龚六堂和夏杰长,2016,《生产分割的演进路径及其影响因素分析——基于生产阶段数的考察》,《管理世界》第4期,第10~23页和187页。 [10]杨耀武和张平,2021,《中国经济高质量发展的逻辑、测度与治理》,《经济研究》第1期,第26~42页。 [11]周申、曾罡和庄子罐,2012,《开放经济下的中国经济增长核算——考虑贸易条件变动因素的分解》,《世界经济文汇》第2期,第18~27页。 [12]Acemoglu, D. and Azar, P. D. 2020. “Endogenous production networks”, Econometrica, 88 (1):33~82. [13]Acemoglu, D., Akcigit, U. and Kerr, W. 2016. “Networks and the macroeconomy: An empirical exploration”, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 30(1):273~335. [14]Acemoglu, D., Carvalho, V. M., Ozdaglar, A. and Tahbaz Salehi, A. 2012. “The Network Origins of Aggregate Fluctuations”, Econometrica, 80(5):1977~2016. [15]Atalay, E., Hortacsu, A., Roberts, J. and Syverson, C. 2011. “Network structure of production”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(13):5199~5202. [16]Basu, S. and Fernald, J.2002. “Aggregate Productivity and Aggregate Technology”, European Economic Review, 46:963~991. [17]Borensztein, E., and Ostry,J. D. 1996. “Accounting for China's Growth Performance”, The American Economic Review, 86(2):224~228. [18]Baqaee, D.R., and Farhi, E. 2019. “A Short Note on Aggregating Productivity”, Social Science Electronic Publishing. [19]Baqaee, D. R.,and Farhi,E. 2020. “Productivity and Misallocation in General Equilibrium”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 135 (1):105~163. [20]Bigio, S. and J. La’O. 2020. “Distortions in Production Networks” ,The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 135(4):2187~2253. [21]Diewert, W. Erwin and Catherine J. Morrison. 1986. “Adjusting Output and Productivity Indexes for Changes in the Terms of Trade”, Economic Journal, 96(383) : 659~79. [22]Domar, E. D. 1961. “On the measurement of technological change”, The Economic Journal, 71(284):709~729. [23]Hang J., Pravin Krishna and Heiwai Tang. 2020. “Input-Output Networks and Misallocation”, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Working Papers 27983. [24]Hulten, C. R. 1978. “Growth accounting with intermediate inputs”, The Review of Economic Studies, 511~518. [25]Hsieh, C.T. and Klenow, P.J. 2009. “Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and India”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124:1403~1448. [26]Jones, C. I. 2011. “Intermediate Goods and Weak Links in the Theory of Economic Development”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 3:1~28. [27]Krugman, P. 1994. “The Myth of Asia's Miracle”, Foreign Affairs, 73(6):62~78. [28]Liu, E. 2019. “Industrial policies in production networks”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 134 (4),: 1883~1948. [29]Long Jr, J. B. and Plosser, C. I. 1983, “Real business cycles”, Journal of political Economy, 91(1):39~69. [30]Osotimehin, S. 2019. “Aggregate productivity and the allocation of resources over the business cycle”, Review of Economic Dynamics, 32:180~205. [31]Petrin, A. and Levinsohn,J. 2012. “Measuring aggregate productivity growth using plantlevel data”, The RAND Journal of Economics, 43(4):705~725. [32]Restuccia, D. and Rogerson,R. 2008. “Policy Distortions and Aggregate Productivity with Heterogeneous Plants” Review of Economic Dynamics, 11(4):707~720. [33]Solow, R. M.,1957. “ Technical change and the aggregate production function”, The review of Economics and Statistics, 312~320. [34]Young,A. 2003. “Gold into Base Metals: Productivity Growth in the People's Republic of China during the Reform Period”, Journal of Political Economy, 111(6):1220~1261.