Summary:
Both the non-synchronization of information transmission and investors' sentiments are typical characteristics of financial markets. The former creates information asymmetry, and the latter can lead to the overconfidence of investors. However, few studies consider how information asymmetry can arise from the process of information transmission or how the processing and updating of new information may trigger overconfidence of investors. Both these processes can affect stock prices and the explanatory power of existing models. Incorporating these sources of information asymmetry and investors' overconfidence into the traditional financial analytical framework has important theoretical and practical implications and deepens our understanding of the internal logic of stock price changes. This study incorporates information asymmetry and investors' overconfidence into the traditional analytical framework and examines how the process of information transmission in real markets affects stock prices. Following Easley and Hara (2004), we model the transmission process of information as a gradual flow of information, which endogenously generates information asymmetry between investors. We then introduce one of the typical psychological characteristics of investors—overconfidence—and establish a two-stage dynamic sequential pricing model to explore whether stock prices are driven by the dual factors of information asymmetry and investors' overconfidence. The main results show that first when investors are presented with new information, adjustments in their expectations of stock returns are positively correlated with the equilibrium price of stocks, that is, increasing investors' expectations of stock returns increases the equilibrium price of stocks, and vice versa. Second, when presented with good news, the proportion of investors who are overconfident tends to increase, the equilibrium prices of stocks increase, and stock returns decline. When presented with bad news, the proportion of investors who are overconfident tends to increase, and both the equilibrium price of stocks and investment loss decline.Third, as the proportion of overconfident investors and the degree of overconfidence increase, the market risk premium decreases. Fourth, investor groups diverge during the process of information transmission, forming heterogeneous beliefs; specifically, investors who have not obtained information and who have not become overconfident think that the stock price is overvalued, whereas investors who have obtained information and who are overconfident think that the price is undervalued, which triggers changes in market volume and stock prices. Fifth, both the proportion of overconfident investors and the increase in overconfidence have a positive impact on market efficiency but a negative effect on market depth. Finally, we use the theoretical results of this study to explain typical volatility characteristics such as asymmetric effects and volatility persistence in real markets. This study extends the literature in three ways. First, it examines how the gradual flow of information into the stock markets creates potential information asymmetry among investors, which affects the formation of equilibrium stock prices. This is a useful supplement to research on information transmission in the stock markets. Second, based on the self-attribution bias theory, we incorporate a typical behavioral bias of investors ̄ ̄—overconfidence—into our model of the information transmission process, which allows us to consider more realistic market environments. We then explore how stock price formation and changes are driven by the dual factors of information asymmetry and investors' overconfidence, expanding the research on stock pricing and price changes. Finally, we use our theoretical results to analyze market price fluctuations, and find that we can explain typical features such as asymmetry and persistence. This enhances the understanding of the logic of stock price changes in real markets.
Abreu, M.,and V., Mendes, 2012, “Information, Overconfidence and Trading: Do the Sources of Information Matter?”, Journal of Economic Psychology, 33(4), pp.868~881.
[11]
Albuquerque Rui and Jianjun Miao, 2014, “Advance Information and Asset Prices”, Journal of Economic Theory, 149, pp.236~275.
[12]
Bekaert, G., and Wu, G. 2000, “Asymmetric Volatility and Risk in Equity Markets”, Review of Financial Studies, 13(1), pp.1~42.
[13]
Bradyn Breon-Drish, 2015, “On Existence and Uniqueness of Equilibrium in a Class of Noisy Rational Expectations Models”, Review of Economic Studies, 82(3), pp.868~921.
[14]
Burks, Stephen V., Middle bury, Lorenz Goette and Aldo Rustichini, 2013, “Overconfidence and Social Signaling”, Review of Economic Studies, 80 (3), pp.949~983 .
[15]
Daniel, K. D., D. Hirshleifer, and A. Subrahmanyam, 2001, “Overconfidence, Arbitrage, and Equilibrium Asset Pricing”, Journal of Finance, 56, pp.921~965.
[16]
De Bondt, W. F.M. and Thaler, R., 1985, “Does the Stock Market Overreact?” Journal of Finance, 40 (3), pp. 793~805.
[17]
Easley, D., and M. O' Hara, 2004, “Information and the Cost of Capital”, Journal of Finance, 59, pp.1553~1583.
[18]
Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, 1977, “Knowing with Certainty: the Appropriateness of Extreme Confidence”.Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance, 3(4), pp.552~564.
[19]
Garcia, D., Sangiorgi, F., and Urosevic, B. 2007, “Overconfidence and Market Efficiency with Heterogeneous Agents.” Economic Theory, 30(2), pp. 313~336.
[20]
Gervais, Simon, and Terrance Odean, 2001, “Learning to Be Overconfident”, Review of Financial Studies, 14(1), pp.1~27.
[21]
Heller, Yuval, 2014, “Overconfidence and Diversification”, American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 6(1), pp.134~153.
[22]
Holden and A., Subrahmanyam, 2002, “News Events, Information Acquisition, and Serial Correlation”, Journal of Business, 75(1), pp.1~32.
[23]
Hong, Harrison, and Jeremy C. Stein, 1999, “A Unified Theory of under Reaction, Momentum Trading and Overreaction in Asset Markets”, Journal of Finance, 54(6), pp.2143~84.
[24]
Huberman, Gur, and Tomer Regev, 2001, “Contagious Speculation and a Cure for Cancer: A Nonevent that Made Stock Prices Soar”, Journal of Finance, 56(1), pp.387~96.
[25]
Jeremy Ko, and Z, Huang, 2007, “Arrogance Can Be a Virtue: Overconfidence, Information Acquisition, and Market Efficiency”, Journal of Financial Economics, 84, pp.529~560.
[26]
Kelly, B., and A., Ljungqvist, 2012, “Testing Asymmetric-Information Asset Pricing Models”, Review of Financial Studies, 25(5), pp.1366~1413.
[27]
Odean, T., 1998, “Volume, Volatility, Price, and Profit When All Traders are Above Average”, Journal of Finance, 53, pp.1887~1934.
[28]
Sandroni and F. Squintani, 2013, “Overconfidence and Asymmetric Information: The Case of Insurance”, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 93(9), pp.149~165.
[29]
Scheinkman, Jose, and Wei Xiong, 2003, “Overconfidence and Speculative Bubbles”, Journal of Political Economy, 111(6), pp.1183~1219.
[30]
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D., 1974, “Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases”, Science, 185(4157), pp.1124~1131.