Summary:
Many countries, including China, have adopted fiscal policies such as tax cuts and subsidies to boost consumption. However, how effective these policies are is a matter of some debate. Previous studies have traditionally focused on relatively poor families because they have higher marginal propensity to consume (MPC) and therefore fiscal policy oriented to such families should be more effective (Galí et al., 2007, Morita 2015). Carroll et al. (2014) further show that the more inequality, the higher aggregate MPC in response to temporary income shocks. These studies follow Campbell and Mankiw (1989, 1990) in describing the poor as those who consume all their income, namely, hand-to-mouth (HtM) households, in contrast to households that do not do so and typically have greater wealth (non-HtM). Wealthy or non-HtM households have low MPC. However, such studies have neglected the possibility that even wealthy households may also have high MPC. The idea is that some wealthy households may have a large amount of illiquid assets but few liquid assets, versus households that have both. These families do not usually liquidify their asset holdings to make consumption smoother, and they therefore tend to consume more in response to a temporary income shock (due to tax cuts or subsidies). Kaplan and Violante (2014a, 2014b) formalize this scenario and re-categorize this group of households as “wealthy HtM households.” Such households are wealthy in terms of total wealth but are HtM because they consume almost all their income. Our first contribution is to re-examine the strategy for selecting types of households and quantifying the shares of different households. We focus on the consumption behavior of urban households and exclude those living in rural areas, as the former have more reliable data and regular income flows. We differ from previous studies of China in that we use four rounds of China Households Finance Survey (CHFS) data (from 2011, 2013, 2015, 2017) and perform a more thorough analysis by comparing different selection criteria. We consider the following concerns. First, Chinese households are more prone to savings and keep more liquid assets. Second, the liquidity of assets is slightly different compared other countries. In particular, we take time deposits, bank issued investment products, and treasury bonds as liquid assets because they have much lower returns and higher liquidity than real estate, the main component of illiquid assets in China. We apply different thresholds of liquid assets over yearly income ratio to determine which households are HtM, complemented by the consumption over income ratio, which is also used in Kaplan and Violante (2014). We find a significantly higher threshold of liquid assets over yearly income ratio, 1/4, than has been used in the literature (1/24). Considering real estate as the main component of illiquid assets, we also use the net value of housing (total market value minus debt and mortgage) to determine whether a household is wealthy. With this selection strategy, we find the following evidence from Chinese urban households. First, the wealthy HtM share is about 36.7%, higher than the upper bounds estimated by He and Zang (2016) and Cui and Feng (2017). We then estimate the heterogeneity of consumption behavior over different types of households. The estimated consumption income elasticities for poor HtM and wealthy HtM households are 4.4% and 5.9% higher than wealthy non-HtM households, respectively. The MPCs to temporary income for poor HtM and wealthy HtM households are 0.069 and 0.09, compared to 0.045 for wealthy non-HtM households. Another contribution of the paper is its recognition of the fact that most households in China must save a high down payment to buy real estate. These households have relatively more liquid assets and negligible illiquid assets. They have smaller MPC compared to wealthy non-HtM households, as shown in a previous study (Zang and Zhang, 2018). Their consumption income elasticity is also 2.7% lower than that of wealthy non-HtM households. Our study has several policy implications. First, we show that the share of wealthy HtM households is larger than previously reported in urban China. These households have high MPC and should be targeted by policies intended to boost aggregate consumption. Second, there is a significant group of poor non-HtM households in China that should not be ignored.
[1]贺洋和臧旭恒,2016,《家庭财富、消费异质性与消费潜力释放》,《经济学动态》,第3期,第56~66页。 [2]李涛和陈斌开,2014,《家庭固定资产、财富效应与居民消费:来自中国城镇家庭的经验证据》,《经济研究》,第3期,第62~75页。 [3]裴育和徐炜锋,2017,《中国家庭房产财富与家庭消费——基于CFPS数据的实证分析》,《审计与经济研究》, 第4期,第93~104页。 [4]臧旭恒和张欣,2018,《中国家庭资产配置与异质性消费者行为分析》,《经济研究》,第3期,第21~34页。 [5]张浩、易行健和周聪,2017,《房产价值变动、城镇居民消费与财富效应异质性——来自微观家庭调查数据的分析》,《金融研究》,第8期,第50~66页。 [6]Campbell J Y and Mankiw N G,1989, “Consumption, Income, and Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence”, NBER macroeconomics annual, No.4, pp. 185~216. [7]Campbell J Y and Mankiw N G ,1990, “Permanent Income, Current Income, and Consumption”, Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, No.3, pp. 265~279. [8]Carroll C D, Slacalek J and Tokuoka K,2014, “The Distribution of Wealth and the MPC: Implications of New European Data”, American Economic Review, No.5, pp.107~111. [9]Cui Z and Feng Y, 2017, “Wealthy Hand‐to‐Mouth Households in China”, Asian Economic Journal, No.3, pp. 275~297. [10]Fang H, Gu and Q, Xiong W ,2016, “Demystifying the Chinese Housing Boom”, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, No.30, pp.105~166. [11]Galí J, López‐Salido J D and Vallés J,2007, “Understanding the Effects of Government Spending on Consumption”, Journal of the European Economic Association, No.1, pp.227~270. [12]Gisle James Natvik,2012, “Government Spending Shocks and Rule-of-Thumb Consumers with Steady-State Inequality”, The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, No.4, pp.1414~1436. [13]Hara R, Unayama T and Weidner J,2016, “The Wealthy Hand to Mouth in Japan”, Economics Letters, No.141.pp.52~54. [14]Hiroshi Morita, 2015, “State-dependent Effects of Fiscal Policy in Japan: Do Rule-of-thumb Households Increase the Effects of Fiscal Policy?”, Journal of Macroeconomics,No.43.pp.49~61. [15]Johnson D S, Parker J A and Souleles N S , 2006, “Household Expenditure and the Income Tax Rebates of 2001”, American Economic Review, No.5, pp.1589-1610. [16]Jordi Galí, Javier Vallés and J. David López-Salido,2005, “Understanding the Effects of Government Spending on Consumption”, Journal of the European Economic Association ,No.1,pp.227~270. [17]Kaplan G and Violante G L ,2010, “How Much Consumption Insurance beyond Self-insurance? ”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, vol.2, No.4,pp.53~87. [18]Kaplan G and Violante G L ,2014, “A Model of the Consumption Response to Fiscal Stimulus Payments”, Econometrica, No.4, pp.1199~1239. [19]Kaplan G and Violante G L,2014, “A Tale of Two Stimulus Payments: 2001 Versus 2008”, American Economic Review, No.5, pp.16~21. [20]Kaplan G, Violante G L and Weidner J, 2014, “The Wealthy Hand-to-mouth”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No.1, pp. 77~153. [21]Mankiw N G, 2000, “The Savers-spenders Theory of Fiscal Policy”, American Economic Review, No.2, pp.120~125. [22]Mian A, Rao K and Sufi A ,2013, “Household Balance Sheets, Consumption, and the Economic Slump”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, No.4, pp. 1687~1726. [23]Morita H, 2015, “State-dependent Effects of Fiscal Policy in Japan: Do Rule-of-thumb Households Increase the Effects of Fiscal Policy?”,Journal of Macroeconomics,No.43, pp. 49~61. [24]Parker J A, Souleles N S and Johnson D S,2013, “Consumer Spending and the Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008”, American Economic Review, No.6, pp. 2530~2553. [25]Poterba J M,2000, “Stock Market Wealth and Consumption”, Journal of economic perspectives, No.2, pp. 99~118.