Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2024, Vol. 534 Issue (12): 116-133    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
同行业补贴外部性与企业进口贸易的技术结构变化
皮建才, 罗禹涵
南京大学经济学院,江苏南京 210093
Industry-wide Subsidy Externality and Technical Structural Changes in Firms' Import Trade
PI Jiancai, LUO Yuhan
School of Economics, Nanjing University
下载:  PDF (734KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 对特定企业的补贴政策会对同行业其他企业的投入品决策产生重要影响。本文基于中国工业企业数据库和海关数据库的匹配数据,考察补贴的同行业外部性与我国企业进口贸易技术结构的潜在联系。实证研究发现:(1)补贴政策会使同行业企业的进口贸易技术结构向“高技术化”转变。(2)这一效应是两种相互对立的力量共同作用的结果:需求效应促使同行业企业进口结构向“低技术化”转变,而竞争效应则推动其向“高技术化”转变,但实证结果表明需求效应的影响相对较弱,因此总体表现为“高技术化”。(3)同行业企业的高技术商品进口规模增长显著,但伴生的供应链风险部分可控。本文揭示了补贴政策在企业进口决策上的非预期效果,为未来如何优化补贴政策以兼顾高水平对外开放与保障产业链供应链安全提供一定启示。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
皮建才
罗禹涵
关键词:  新发展格局  进口贸易  技术结构  补贴外部性    
Summary:  The new development paradigm features dual circulation, in which domestic and foreign markets reinforce each other, with the domestic market as the mainstay. Since joining the World Trade Organization, Chinese enterprises have improved their productivity through high-technology imports. However, in the complex and volatile international environment, such imports also increase the risk of the supply chain. Given the varying importance of different technology types in trade, it is reasonable and necessary to focus on the technical structure of trade rather than just its scale.
Subsidy policies targeted at specific firms can have an important impact on the input decisions of other firms in the same domestic industry, which in turn affects the technical structure of these firms' import trade. However, this phenomenon has received little attention in the existing empirical literature. The primary channels for these externalities are the intermediate input and product markets. Subsidized firms, with additional supports, increase their demand for intermediate inputs, driving up domestic prices (referred to as the demand effect). They can also adopt more diverse competitive strategies at lower costs, increasing market competition for other firms (referred to as the competition effect).
The demand effect motivates firms within the same industry to import to mitigate the impact of rising domestic input prices. This effect mainly manifests as an increase in the prices of low-technology goods. For subsidized firms, expanding low-technology inputs is easier and faster than high-technology counterparts due to higher associated costs. Low-technology goods, being more homogeneous, can transmit price shocks across the nation more easily. Thus, the demand effect primarily encourages other firms to import low-technology goods as substitutes for their current inputs.
The competition effect motivates firms to import high-technology goods to enhance their product competitiveness and alleviate increased competitive pressures. Whether improving existing products or developing new ones, importing high-technology goods offers more learning opportunities than low-technology ones. Therefore, the competition effect primarily promotes the import of high-technology goods.
We use matched data from the Chinese Annual Survey of Industrial Enterprises and the Customs Database to examine the potential relationship between the aforementioned externalities of subsidies and the technical structure of import trade by Chinese firms. This paper shows that when the subsidy intensity in an industry increases, the technical structure of imports shifts towards high technology. The mechanism analysis indicates that both demand and competition effects exist, though the former has a relatively weaker impact. The further analysis reveals a significant increase in the scale of high-technology imports. Although supply chain risks objectively increase, they are partially manageable because firms tend to import goods with domestic exporter guarantees.
Compared to existing literature, the main contributions of this paper are reflected in the following three aspects. First, this paper focuses on the import trade technical structure of enterprises, which is closely related to key issues such as the autonomy and controllability of industrial chains and high-level opening-up. Second, this paper explores the impact of subsidies on the import trade technical structure from the perspective of externalities, providing a supplement to the existing literature. Third, this paper discusses and examines the specific mechanism of industry-wide subsidy externalities on the import trade technical structure.
The findings in this paper have important policy implications. First, the government should comprehensively assess the impact of subsidy policies on other non-beneficiary firms in the same industry, ensuring that policies consider both direct and indirect effects. Second, the government should carefully manage the input price fluctuations caused by the demand effect to minimize adverse impacts on related firms. Third, the government should support enterprise transformation and upgrading to fully leverage the positive effects of the competition effect. Fourth, the government should establish and improve supply chain risk management mechanisms.
Keywords:  New Development Paradigm    Import Trade    Technical Structure    Subsidy Externality
JEL分类号:  F14   H23   O11  
基金资助: * 感谢匿名审稿人的宝贵意见,文责自负。
作者简介:  皮建才,经济学博士,教授,南京大学经济学院,E-mail:pi2008@nju.edu.cn.
罗禹涵,博士研究生,南京大学经济学院,E-mail:Ecomons@outlook.com.
引用本文:    
皮建才, 罗禹涵. 同行业补贴外部性与企业进口贸易的技术结构变化[J]. 金融研究, 2024, 534(12): 116-133.
PI Jiancai, LUO Yuhan. Industry-wide Subsidy Externality and Technical Structural Changes in Firms' Import Trade. Journal of Financial Research, 2024, 534(12): 116-133.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2024/V534/I12/116
[1]安同良、周绍东和皮建才,2009,《R&D补贴对中国企业自主创新的激励效应》,《经济研究》第10期,第 87~98+120 页。
[2]柏培文和喻理,2021,《数字经济发展与企业价格加成:理论机制与经验事实》,《中国工业经济》第11期,第 59~77 页。
[3]何晴、刘净然和范庆泉,2022,《企业研发风险与补贴政策优化研究》,《经济研究》第5期,第 192~208 页。
[4]何祚宇、高重阳和李敬子,2022,《中国外部循环内部化的潜力、短板与福利——基于保留价格和供需匹配的视角》,《中国工业经济》第6期,第 24~41 页。
[5]江小涓、孟丽君和魏必,2023,《以高水平分工和制度型开放提升跨境资源配置效率》,《经济研究》第8期,第 15~31 页。
[6]蒋冠宏,2022,《中国产业政策的均衡效应分析——基于政府补贴的视角》,《中国工业经济》第6期,第 98~116 页。
[7]李胜旗和毛其淋,2017,《制造业上游垄断与企业出口国内附加值——来自中国的经验证据》,《中国工业经济》第3期,第 101~119 页。
[8]林毅夫、巫和懋和邢亦青,2010,《“潮涌现象”与产能过剩的形成机制》,《经济研究》第10期,第 4~19 页。
[9]吕越、罗伟和刘斌,2015,《异质性企业与全球价值链嵌入:基于效率和融资的视角》,《世界经济》第8期,第 29~55 页。
[10]聂辉华、李光武和李琛,2022,《关于企业补贴的八个关键问题——兼评当下的产业政策研究》,《学术月刊》第6期,第 47~60 页。
[11]邵敏和包群,2012,《政府补贴与企业生产率——基于我国工业企业的经验分析》,《中国工业经济》第7期,第 70~82 页。
[12]孙秀林和周飞舟,2013,《土地财政与分税制:一个实证解释》,《中国社会科学》第4期,第 40~59+205 页。
[13]王海成、张伟豪和夏紫莹,2023,《产业规模偏好与企业全要素生产率——来自省级政府五年规划文本的证据》,《经济研究》第5期,第 153~171 页。
[14]王永进和施炳展,2014,《上游垄断与中国企业产品质量升级》,《经济研究》第4期,第 116~129 页。
[15]魏浩和李晓庆,2015,《中国进口贸易的技术结构及其影响因素研究》,《世界经济》第8期,第 56~79 页。
[16]吴伟伟和张天一,2021,《非研发补贴与研发补贴对新创企业创新产出的非对称影响研究》,《管理世界》第3期,第 137~160+10 页。
[17]许家云、毛其淋和胡鞍钢,2017,《中间品进口与企业出口产品质量升级:基于中国证据的研究》,《世界经济》第3期,第 52~75 页。
[18]许家云和毛其淋,2019,《生产性补贴与企业进口行为:来自中国制造业企业的证据》,《世界经济》第7期,第 46~70 页。
[19]叶光亮、程龙和张晖,2022,《竞争政策强化及产业政策转型影响市场效率的机理研究——兼论有效市场与有为政府》,《中国工业经济》第1期,第 74~92 页。
[20]余淼杰和李晋,2015,《进口类型、行业差异化程度与企业生产率提升》,《经济研究》第8期,第 85~97+113 页。
[21]张杰、陈志远、杨连星和新夫,2015,《中国创新补贴政策的绩效评估:理论与证据》,《经济研究》第10期,第 4~17+33 页。
[22]章元、程郁和佘国满,2018,《政府补贴能否促进高新技术企业的自主创新?——来自中关村的证据》,《金融研究》第10期,第 123~140 页。
[23]诸竹君、宋学印、张胜利和陈丽芳,2021,《产业政策、创新行为与企业加成率——基于战略性新兴产业政策的研究》,《金融研究》第6期,第 59~75 页。
[24]Acemoglu, D. and J. Angrist, 2000, “How Large Are Human-Capital Externalities? Evidence from Compulsory Schooling Laws”, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 15, pp.9~59.
[25]Goldsmith-Pinkham, P., I. Sorkin and H. Swift, 2020, “Bartik Instruments: What, When, Why, and How”, American Economic Review, 110(8), pp.2586~2624.
[26]Kalemli-Ozcan, S., B. Sorensen and V. Volosovych, 2014, “Deep Financial Integration and Volatility”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 12(6), pp.1558~1585.
[27]Lach, S., 2002, “Do R&D Subsidies Stimulate or Displace Private R&D? Evidence from Israel”, Journal of Industrial Economics, 50(4), pp.369~390.
[28]Lall, S., 2000, “The Technological Structure and Performance of Developing Country Manufactured Exports, 1985‐98”, Oxford Development Studies, 28(3), pp.337~369.
[29]Levinsohn, J. and A. Petrin, 2003, “Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables”, Review of Economic Studies, 70(2), pp.317~341.
[30]Liu, E., 2019, “Industrial Policies in Production Networks”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 134(4), pp.1883~1948.
[31]Loecker, J. D. and F. Warzynski, 2012, “Markups and Firm-Level Export Status”, American Economic Review, 102(6), pp.2437~2471.
[32]Rotemberg, M., 2019, “Equilibrium Effects of Firm Subsidies”, American Economic Review, 109(10), pp.3475~3513.
[33]Upward, R., Z. Wang and J. Zheng, 2013, “Weighing China's Export Basket: The Domestic Content and Technology Intensity of Chinese Exports”, Journal of Comparative Economics, 41(2), pp.527~543.
[1] 魏浩, 白明浩, 郭也. 融资约束与中国企业的进口行为[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 464(2): 98-116.
[2] 魏浩, 巫俊. 知识产权保护、进口贸易与创新型领军企业创新[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 459(9): 91-106.
[1] 马理, 娄田田, 牛慕鸿. 定向降准与商业银行行为选择[J]. 金融研究, 2015, 423(9): 82 -95 .
[2] 郑济孝. XBRL格式财务报告对中国股市有效性的影响研究[J]. 金融研究, 2015, 426(12): 194 -207 .
[3] 温信祥, 苏乃芳. 大资管、影子银行与货币政策传导[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 460(10): 38 -54 .
[4] 饶品贵, 罗勇根. 通货膨胀如何影响股票回报——基于债务融资的视角[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 433(7): 160 -175 .
[5] 陈关亭, 连立帅, 朱松. 多重信用评级与债券融资成本——来自中国债券市场的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 488(2): 94 -113 .
[6] 吴立元, 赵扶扬, 王忏, 龚六堂. 美国货币政策溢出效应、中国资产价格波动与资本账户管理[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 493(7): 77 -94 .
[7] 张伟华, 毛新述, 刘凯璇. 利率市场化改革降低了上市公司债务融资成本吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 460(10): 106 -122 .
[8] 诸竹君, 宋学印, 张胜利, 陈丽芳. 产业政策、创新行为与企业加成率——基于战略性新兴产业政策的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 492(6): 59 -75 .
[9] 张琳琳, 沈红波, 范剑青. 证券投资基金规模适度性研究——基于中国市场的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 501(3): 189 -206 .
[10] 景光正, 李平, 许家云. 金融结构、双向FDI与技术进步[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 445(7): 62 -77 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1