Summary:
The coexistence of a high savings rate and high leverage ratio has been a typical feature of China's economy in recent years. The high savings rate is also considered one of the main reasons for China's high leverage. Therefore, whether deleveraging can be achieved by reducing the savings rate has become a widely discussed issue. Unfortunately, the research has not definitively answered this question. Moreover, in reality, the following two phenomena do not support a positive correlation between the savings rate and leverage ratio. First, a high savings rate is a long-standing phenomenon in China's economy, but high leverage is a problem that only emerged after the 2008 global financial crisis. Second, at the international level, countries with low savings and high leverage are more common than countries with high savings and high leverage. Accordingly, this paper conducts a more systematic analysis of the relationship between savings rate and leverage ratio by means of theoretical models and empirical tests. In terms of theoretical models, this paper constructs a dynamic general equilibrium model based on the Samuelson-Diamond-Tirole OLG framework with financing constraints, including households and enterprises. The model depicts the two main effects of savings rate on leverage. For example, a decline in the savings rate will enable the household sector to allocate more funds to in consumption and financial assets, which is reflected in the increase in leverage incentives in the household sector; at the same time, it will reduce the size of loanable funds available to the corporate sector, which will affect the lending and investment decisions of that sector. The numerical simulation results show that the relationship between the savings rate and leverage ratio is not monotonic but U-shaped. Furthermore, based on the theoretical model, this paper finds that in the high leverage state, the lower savings rate means a greater probability of financial crisis in the economy. In contrast, higher savings rates usually correspond to the highly leveraged state of the corporate sector, often leading to inefficient credit allocation in the corporate sector. Although this problem will bring about the loss of economic efficiency, it is less likely to trigger a financial crisis. In terms of empirical tests, this paper takes 41 representative economies commonly used by the Bank for International Settlements as a sample. Based on panel data from 1966 to 2017, this paper empirically analyzes the relationship between savings rate and leverage ratio. Both a static panel fixed-effect regression model and a dynamic panel Arellano-Bond system estimation method show a robust U-shaped relationship between savings rate and leverage ratio. The conclusion is consistent with the numerical simulation results of the theoretical model. Based on the financial crisis data of major economies from 1966 to 2010 and using Probit and Logit models, this paper finds that a higher savings rate under high leverage can effectively reduce the probability of a financial crisis, while a decline in the savings rate increases the probability of a financial crisis, which agrees with the conclusions reached by the theoretical model. In addition to the preceding results, it is expected that changes in China's savings rate will have two effects. First, because the savings rate and leverage ratio show a U-shaped relationship with an inflection point at around 39%, reducing China's savings rate (47% in 2017) will help to reduce leverage. However, further calculations show that this leverage reduction effect is more limited. Even if China's savings rate is reduced to the inflection point, the leverage ratio can only drop by about 4 percentage points. Second, the critical value of the impact of the savings rate on the probability of a financial crisis under high leverage is around 48%; that is, when the savings rate is lower than 48%, it will not be enough to offset the risk of financial crisis caused by the increase in leverage. The decline in China's savings rate in the future will exacerbate financial risks and increase the likelihood of a financial crisis. Consequently, this paper argues that China cannot reduce the leverage ratio by reducing the savings rate. Instead, it needs to address the decline in the savings rate in recent years. The research in this paper will not only help deepen public understanding of China's high leverage problem and how to deal with it but will also serve as a reference for the formulation of macro policy in China's structural deleveraging process.
[1]陈彦斌、刘哲希和陈伟泽,2018,《经济增速放缓下的资产泡沫研究——基于含有高债务特征的动态一般均衡模型》,《经济研究》第10期,第18~34页。 [2]陈彦斌、郭豫媚和姚一旻,2014,《人口老龄化对中国储蓄率的影响》,《金融研究》第1期,第71~84页。 [3]冯明,2016,《宏观债务管理的政策框架及其结构性去杠杆》,《改革》第7期,第104~114页。 [4]纪敏、严宝玉和李宏瑾,2017,《杠杆率结构、水平和金融稳定——理论分析框架和中国经验》,《金融研究》第2期,第15~29页。 [5]李宏瑾、苏乃芳和洪浩,2016,《价格型货币政策调控中的实际利率锚》,《经济研究》第1期,第42~54页。 [6]李扬和殷剑峰,2005,《劳动力转移过程中的高储蓄、高投资和中国经济增长》,《经济研究》第2期,第4~15页。 [7]刘哲希和李子昂,2018,《结构性去杠杆进程中居民部门可以加杠杆吗?》,《中国工业经济》第10期,第44~62页。 [8]马建堂、董小君和时红秀,2016,《中国的杠杆率与系统性金融风险防范》,《财贸经济》第1期,第5~21页。 [9]马勇和陈雨露,2017,《金融杠杆、杠杆波动与经济增长》,《经济研究》第6期,第33~47页。 [10]孙国峰和何晓贝,2017,《存款利率零下限与负利率传导机制》,《经济研究》第12期,第105~118页。 [11]汪伟,2010,《计划生育政策的储蓄与增长效应:理论与中国的经验分析》,《经济研究》第10期,第63~77页。 [12]吴国培、王伟斌和张习宁,2015,《新常态下的中国经济增长潜力分析》,《金融研究》第8期,第46~63页。 [13]徐丽芳、许志伟和王鹏飞,2017,《金融发展与国民储蓄率:一个倒U型关系》,《经济研究》第2期,第113~124页。 [14]张成思和张步昙,2016,《中国实业投资率下降之谜:经济金融化视角》,《经济研究》第12期32~46页。 [15]钟宁桦、刘志阔、何嘉鑫和苏楚林,2016,《我国企业债务的结构性问题》,《经济研究》第7期,第102~117页。 [16]张斌、何晓贝和邓欣,2018,《不一样的杠杆——从国际比较看杠杆上升的现象、原因与影响》,《金融研究》第2期,第15~29页。 [17]周小川,2009:《关于储蓄率问题的若干观察与分析》,《中国金融》第4期,第45~47页。 [18]Bernanke, B. S., 2008, “Remarks On the Economic Outlook”, Speeches at the International Monetary Conference, June 3. [19]Brunnermeier, M. K., and M. Oehmke, 2013, “Bubbles, Financial Crises, and Systemic Risk”, Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Volume 2B, Chapter 18: 1221~1288. [20]Dalio, R., 2018, A Template For Understanding Big Debt Crises, November Media Publishing & Consulting Firm. [21]Drehmann, M., 2013, “Evaluating Early Warning Indicators of Banking Crises: Satisfying Policy Requirements”, BIS Working Papers, No. 421. [22]Martin, A., and J. Ventura, 2016, “Managing Credit Bubbles”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 14(3): 753~789. [23]Mian, A., and A. Sufi, 2014, House of Debt: How They(and you) Caused the Great Recession and How We Can Prevent It From Happening Again, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. [24]Reinhart, C. M., and K. S. Rogoff, 2009, This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly, New Jersey: Princeton University Press. [25]Reinhart, C. M., 2010, “This Time is Different Chartbook: Country Histories on Debt, Default, and Financial Crises,” NBER Working Paper, No. 15815. [26]Tirole, J., 1985, “Asset Bubbles and Overlapping Generations”, Econometrica, 53(6): 1499~1528.