Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2023, Vol. 511 Issue (1): 21-38    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
劳动力市场性别差距、生产结构转型与人口增长转变
郭凯明, 王钰冰, 颜色
中山大学岭南学院,广东广州 510275;
北京大学光华管理学院,北京 100871
The Gender Gap in the Labor Market, Structural Transformation, and Demographic Transition
GUO Kaiming, WANG Yubing, YAN Se
Lingnan College, Sun Yat-sen University;
Guanghua School of Management, Peking University
下载:  PDF (1336KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 本文从劳动力市场性别差距视角为理解生产结构转型与人口增长转变的互动关系提出了新的理论机制。以脑力劳动密集型生产部门比重提高为特征的生产结构转型将缩小性别工资差距,提高家庭生育养育机会成本并降低生育率,进而增加女性劳动相对供给,这又会进一步提高脑力劳动密集型生产部门比重。直接干预女性劳动定价政策可能会带来女性结构性失业,反而扩大劳动力市场性别差距,且不利于生产结构转型;单方面降低女性生育养育成本政策虽然能够提高生育率,但也可能产生类似不利影响;降低男性生育养育成本政策既可以提高生育率,又可以缩小劳动力市场性别差距,并促进生产结构转型;生育养育成本补贴支出由政府承担的影响比由企业承担更为温和。本文结果表明,促进人口长期均衡发展的政策应与缩小劳动力市场性别差距、推动生产结构转型的政策统筹谋划和协调推进。本文研究为“优化人口发展战略,建立生育支持政策体系”提供了一定的理论依据和参考。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
郭凯明
王钰冰
颜色
关键词:  人口增长  生育率  结构转型  性别差距    
Summary:  The modernization of China is inextricably linked to its population. China is undergoing a rapid demographic transition, with a falling fertility rate, an aging population, and a shrinking population dividend. China's labor force has been decreasing since 2015, and its population peaked around 2021. Meanwhile, China's economy is undergoing a salient structural transformation, with a new technological revolution, a new wave of industrial change, and a rapid increase in high-tech manufacturing and modern services on the horizon. This structural transformation may affect population growth, while the demographic transition may also affect the structure of the economy. The relationship between these two processes and the related effects require comprehensive study to help China promote long-term, balanced population growth and promote structural transformation during this new development stage.
We propose a new theoretical mechanism of the gender gap in the labor market to better understand the relationship between structural transformation and demographic transition. Our novel dynamic general equilibrium model incorporates the endogenous evolution of the gender gap in the labor market, structural transformation, and population growth. The model also allows us to fully capture the structural effects of related policies, such as directly intervening in the price of female labor or lowering fertility costs. We focus on the gender gap in the labor market for three main reasons. First, the share of female employment differs greatly among sectors in China, and the sectoral shares of output vary. Second, the industries with the largest share of female labor are mostly skill-intensive. Skilled labor relies on mental labor, whereas unskilled labor relies on physical labor. Compared with male workers, female workers have an advantage in supplying mental labor relative to physical labor. Third, women have an advantage over men in raising children.
We find that because the structural transformation process increases the share of mental-labor-intensive sectors, it narrows the gender wage gap, increasing fertility costs and thus decreasing the fertility rate. This in turn increases the relative supply of female labor and mental labor. When the elasticity of substitution between sectoral outputs is high, the share of mental-labor-intensive sectors continues to increase. Hence, the economy experiences a dynamic transition in which the share of mental-labor-intensive sectors increases, the gender wage gap narrows, the relative supply of female labor increases, and the population growth rate falls. We also find that a policy to intervene in the price of female labor, which is intended to narrow the gender wage gap, may instead result in the structural unemployment of women, widen the gender gap in the labor market, and slow structural transformation. A policy to lower women's fertility costs would increase the fertility rate, but it could have the same side effects. In contrast, a policy to lower the fertility costs of men would increase the fertility rate, narrow the gender gap in the labor market, and promote structural transformation. We also find that the adverse effects of subsidizing childbirth may be reduced when sponsored by the government rather than firms. Thus, a policy to further lower men's fertility costs should be coordinated with a policy to lower those of women, with the former sponsored by firms and the latter by the government.
We derive the policy implications of these findings by suggesting policies to promote long-term, balanced population growth, narrow the gender gap in the labor market, and spur structural transformation. Moreover, the government should establish policies that simultaneously encourage families to have children, improve the structure of the labor supply, and narrow the gender gap. First, the government should act to reduce the opportunity costs of fertility, particularly for men. Second, the government should reduce the economic burden of having children and support firms with more tax breaks and public spending. Third, the government could also explore alternative ways to increase birth rates through public spending and tax reductions.
This paper contributes to the literature by systematically analyzing the relationship between the gender gap in the labor market and China's ongoing structural transformation and demographic transition. The conclusions offer a novel mechanism through which structural transformation and demographic changes affect each other and a comprehensive framework with which to evaluate the structural effects of related policies.
Keywords:  Population Growth    Fertility    Structural Transformation    Gender Gap
JEL分类号:  J11   O11   O41  
基金资助: * 本文感谢国家自然科学基金面上项目(71973156、71973006)、国家社会科学基金重大项目(22ZDA049)资助。感谢匿名审稿人的宝贵意见,文责自负。
通讯作者:  王钰冰,经济学博士研究生,中山大学岭南学院,E-mail:wangyb6@mailz.sysu.edu.cn.   
作者简介:  郭凯明,经济学博士,副教授,中山大学岭南学院,E-mail:guokm3@mail.sysu.edu.cn.
颜 色,经济学博士,副教授,北京大学光华管理学院,E-mail: seyan@gsm.pku.edu.cn.
引用本文:    
郭凯明, 王钰冰, 颜色. 劳动力市场性别差距、生产结构转型与人口增长转变[J]. 金融研究, 2023, 511(1): 21-38.
GUO Kaiming, WANG Yubing, YAN Se. The Gender Gap in the Labor Market, Structural Transformation, and Demographic Transition. Journal of Financial Research, 2023, 511(1): 21-38.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2023/V511/I1/21
[1] 郭凯明和颜色,2011,《性别偏好与人口转型》,《经济学(季刊)》第4期,第1209~1234页。
[2] 郭凯明和颜色,2015,《性别工资差距、资本积累与人口转变》,《金融研究》第8期,第13~30页。
[3] 郭凯明、颜色和李双潞,2021,《结构转型、生育率选择与人口转变》,《世界经济》第1期,第106~125页。
[4] 汪伟、刘玉飞和彭东东,2015,《人口老龄化的产业结构升级效应研究》,《中国工业经济》第11期,第47~61页。
[5] 鄢伟波和安磊,2021,《中国女性劳动供给为何降低:来自流动人口的证据》,《世界经济》第12期,第104~130页。
[6] 颜色、郭凯明和段雪琴,2021,《老龄化、消费结构与服务业发展》,《金融研究》第2期,第20~37页。
[7] 颜色、郭凯明和杭静,2022,《中国人口红利与产业结构转型》,《管理世界》第4期,第15~33页。
[8] 詹鹏、毛逸波和李实,2021,《城镇女性劳动供给长期趋势研究:来自教育扩张和生育行为的解释》,《中国工业经济》第8期,第56~74页。
[9] Acemoglu, Daron, and Veronica Guerrieri. 2008. “Capital Deepening and Non-balanced Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy, 116(3):467~498.
[10] Adda, Jérôme, Christian Dustmann, and Katrien Stevens. 2017, “The Career Costs of Children”, Journal of Political Economy, 125(2):293~337.
[11] Becker, Gary S., and H. G. Lewis. 1973. “On the Interaction between the Quantity and Quality of Children”, Journal of Political Economy, 81(2):279~288.
[12] Becker, Gary S., Kevin M. Murphy, and Robert Tamura. 1990. “Human Capital, Fertility, and Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy, 98(5):12~37.
[13] Bloom, David E., David Canning, Günther Fink, and Jocelyn E. Finlay. 2009. “Fertility, Female Labor Force Participation, and the Demographic Dividend”, Journal of Economic Growth, 14(2):79~101.
[14] Comin, Diego, Danial Lashkari, and Marti Mestieri. 2021. “Structural Change with Long‐Run Income and Price Effects”, Econometrica, 89(1):311~374.
[15] Cravino, Javier, Andrei Levchenko, and Marco Rojas. 2022. “Population Aging and Structural Transformation”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 14(4):479~498.
[16] Ehrlich, Isaac, and Francis T. Lui. 1991. “Intergenerational Trade, Longevity, and Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy, 99(5):1029~1059.
[17] Gaddis, Isis, and Stephan Klasen. 2014. “Economic Development, Structural Change, and Women's Labor Force Participation: A Reexamination of the Feminization U Hypothesis”, Journal of Population Economics, 27(3):639~681.
[18] Galor, Oded, and David N. Weil. 1996. “The Gender Gap, Fertility, and Growth”, American Economic Review, 86(3):374~387.
[19] Galor, Oded, and David N. Weil. 2000. “Population, Technology, and Growth: From Malthusian Stagnation to the Demographic Transition and Beyond”, American Economic Review, 90(4):806~828.
[20] Greenwood, Jeremy, Ananth Seshadri, and Guillaume Vandenbroucke. 2005. “The Baby Boom and Baby Bust”, American Economic Review, 95(1):183~207.
[21] Kongsamut, Piyabha, Sergio Rebelo, and Dangyang Xie. 2001. “Beyond Balanced Growth”, Review of Economic Studies, 68(4):869~882.
[22] Lagerlof, Nils-Petter. 2003. “Gender Equality and Long-Run Growth”, Journal of Economic Growth, 8(4):403~426.
[23] Leukhina, Oksana M., and Stephen J. Turnovsky. 2016. “Population Size Effects in the Structural Development of England”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 8(3):195~229.
[24] Ngai, L. Rachel, and Barbara Petrongolo. 2017. “Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 9(4):1~44.
[25] Ngai, L. Rachel, and Christopher A. Pissarides. 2007. “Structural Change in a Multisector Model of Growth”, American Economic Review, 97(1):429~443.
[26] Rendall, Michelle. 2013. “Structural Change in Developing Countries:Has it Decreased Gender Inequality?”, World Development, 45:1~16.
[27] Rendall, Michelle. 2017. “Brain versus Brawn: The Realization of Women's Comparative Advantage”, SSRN Working Paper, no. 491.
[28] Simonovska, Ina, and Michael E. Waugh. 2011. “Different Trade Models, Different Trade Elasticities?”, NBER Working Paper, no. 16796.
[29] Strulik, Holger, and Jacob Weisdorf. 2008. “Population, Food, and Knowledge: A Simple Unified Growth Theory”, Journal of Economic Growth, 13(3):195~216.
[30] Vollrath, Dietrich. 2009. “The Dual Economy in Long-Run Development”, Journal of Economic Growth, 14(4):287~312.
[31] Wu, Xiaoyu. 2022. “Fertility and Maternal Labor Supply: Evidence from the New Two-Child Policies in Urban China”, Journal of Comparative Economics, 50(2):584~598.
[1] 卢国军, 崔小勇, 王弟海. 自动化技术、结构转型与中国收入分配格局的演化[J]. 金融研究, 2023, 514(4): 19-35.
[2] 郭凯明, 陈昊, 颜色. 贸易成本与中国制造[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 501(3): 1-19.
[3] 颜色, 郭凯明, 段雪琴. 老龄化、消费结构与服务业发展[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 488(2): 20-37.
[4] 耿志祥, 孙祁祥. 延迟退休年龄、内生生育率与养老金[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 479(5): 77-94.
[5] 张斌, 熊婉婷. 经济结构转型与“双支柱”调控框架[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 92-105.
[6] 张斌, 何晓贝, 邓欢. 不一样的杠杆——从国际比较看杠杆上升的现象、原因与影响[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 452(2): 15-29.
[7] 郭凯明, 余靖雯. 工资增长、生育率差异与人力资本积累——基于内生生育和退休的动态一般均衡研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 441(3): 1-15.
[8] 严成樑, 徐翔. 生产性财政支出与结构转型[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 435(9): 99-114.
[9] 郭凯明, 余靖雯. 城镇化过程中人口增长趋势转变与人口政策[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 430(4): 17-33.
[1] 王曦, 朱立挺, 王凯立. 我国货币政策是否关注资产价格?——基于马尔科夫区制转换BEKK多元GARCH模型[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 1 -17 .
[2] 刘勇政, 李岩. 中国的高速铁路建设与城市经济增长[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 18 -33 .
[3] 况伟大, 王琪琳. 房价波动、房贷规模与银行资本充足率[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 34 -48 .
[4] 祝树金, 赵玉龙. 资源错配与企业的出口行为——基于中国工业企业数据的经验研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 49 -64 .
[5] 陈德球, 陈运森, 董志勇. 政策不确定性、市场竞争与资本配置[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 65 -80 .
[6] 牟敦果, 王沛英. 中国能源价格内生性研究及货币政策选择分析[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 81 -95 .
[7] 高铭, 江嘉骏, 陈佳, 刘玉珍. 谁说女子不如儿郎?——P2P投资行为与过度自信[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 96 -111 .
[8] 吕若思, 刘青, 黄灿, 胡海燕, 卢进勇. 外资在华并购是否改善目标企业经营绩效?——基于企业层面的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 112 -127 .
[9] 姜军, 申丹琳, 江轩宇, 伊志宏. 债权人保护与企业创新[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 128 -142 .
[10] 刘莎莎, 孔高文. 信息搜寻、个人投资者交易与股价联动异象——基于股票送转的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 143 -157 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1