Summary:
Existing literature primarily studies the homogeneous impact of standard implementation on enterprise innovation behavior based on the standard release time. However, enterprises succeed in the competition for standard-setting rights often voluntarily disclose their participation in standard formulation in the core competitiveness section of their annual reports, well before the official standard release time. In contrast, other enterprises in the same industry—those that did not participate in standard formulation, the de facto failed enterprises—are likely to make competitive responses upon learning of their rivals' involvement in the formulation of standards. Modern innovation economics holds that the feedback effect among standards, innovation and markets leave room for counterattack opportunities for enterprises that fail in standard competition. These failed enterprises can turn defeat into victory through high-quality innovation. Therefore, enterprises that fail in the competition for standard-setting rights may use high-quality innovation to counterattack successful enterprises, preventing them from being marginalized in the market or preparing them for victory in the next stage of competition through high-quality innovation. This article identifies enterprises that publicly disclose information on participating in standard formulation as successful enterprises in the competition for standard formulation rights, that is, competitors, while identifying other enterprises in the industry as failed competitors. Based on the theory of standard competition, it explores how enterprises can cope with the failure of the competition for standard formulation rights by improving the quality of innovation. The research findings are as follows: (1) The innovation breakthrough degree of enterprises that fail in the competition for standard-setting rights is significantly positively correlated with that of successful enterprises. This conclusion still holds true after excluding the influence of the simple peer effect, the simple disclosure effect, and strategic information disclosure, indicating that failed enterprises actively respond to the failure in the competition for standard-setting rights by significantly improving the quality of innovation.(2) The competitive innovation response of enterprises mainly occurs in the group with more intense industry innovation competition, the group with weaker innovation capabilities of successful enterprises, and the group with stronger innovation capabilities of failed enterprises. This indicates that when industry innovation competition is intense, failed enterprises have stronger innovation capabilities, and successful enterprises have weaker innovation capabilities, Failed enterprises are more likely to significantly enhance the quality of their innovation to cope with the failure in the competition for the right to set standards. (3) When successful enterprises only participate in the formulation of standards —or are involved in the formulation of industry, local and enterprise-level standards, and the cumulative number of industry standards, the number of newly added standards and the degree of marketization of standards are higher, failed enterprises are more likely to significantly improve the quality of innovation to cope with the failure in the competition for the right to formulate standards. (4) The proactive response of failed enterprises has enhanced the strength of the real economy and reduced the risk of stock price crashes, indicating that the positive response of enterprises to the failure of the competition for the right to set standards in terms of innovation quality is conducive to their future long-term development. There are two marginal contributions in this study. Existing literature focuses on how standards affect enterprise innovation, but fails to pay attention to the heterogeneous manifestations of the impact of standard implementation on the innovation behaviors of enterprises that do not participate in standard formulation and those that do. It also fails to explore based on the standard competition theory how enterprises adjust their innovation strategies to cope with the results of the previous competitive rounds. This article explores how enterprises that have not participated in standard setting can utilize high-quality innovation to make competitive responses to their competitors' participation in standard setting, which can make up for the above-mentioned deficiencies in such literature. Second, although existing literature focuses on the impact of innovation competition on enterprise innovation, it neglects the feedback dynamics between innovation, standards, and the product market. The failure of enterprises in the competition for the right to set standards is likely due to their failure in the innovation competition. The fundamental measure for enterprises to deal with the failure in the competition for the right to set standards is to improve the quality of innovation to gain an innovation competitive advantage. Therefore, this paper studies how enterprises adjust the quality of innovation to cope with the failure in the competition for standard-setting rights, which can make up for the above-mentioned deficiencies of such literature. In conclusion, the research in this paper contributes to a deeper understanding of the relationship between standards and enterprise innovation from the perspective of standard competition.
王雄元, 王慧娴, 王子平. 竞争对手主持或参与标准制定与企业创新质量[J]. 金融研究, 2025, 539(5): 95-113.
WAND XiongYuan, WANG HuiXian, WANG ZiPing. Competitor's Involvemnet in or Hosting of Standard Formulation and the Quality of Enterprise Innovation. Journal of Financial Research, 2025, 539(5): 95-113.
Aggarwal, N., Q. Dai and E.A. Walden, 2011, “The More, the Merrier? How the Number of Partners in a Standard-setting Initiative Affects Shareholder's Risk and Return”, MIS Quarterly, pp.445~462.
[13]
Allen, R. H. and R. D. Sriram,2000, “The Role of Standards in Innovation”, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 64(2-3), pp.171~181.
[14]
Amit, R. and J. Livnat, 1988, “Diversification Strategies, Business Cycles and Economic Performance”, Strategic Management Journal, 9(2),pp.99~110.
[15]
Basse, G., P. Ding, A. Feller and P. Toulis, 2024, “Randomization Tests for Peer Effects in Group Formation Experiments”, Econometrica, 92(2), pp.567~590.
[16]
Blind K. and A. Jungmittag, 2008,“The Impact of Patents and Standards on Macroeconomic Growth:A Panel Approach Covering Four Counties and 12 Sectors”, Journal of Productivity Analysisi, 29(1), pp.51~60.
[17]
Chatterjee, K. and R. Evans, 2004, “Rivals' Search for Buried Treasure: Competition and Duplication in R&D”, RAND Journal of Economics, 35(1), pp.160~183.
[18]
Doraszelski U., 2003, “An R&D Race with Knowledge Accumulation”, RAND Journal of economics, pp.20~42.
[19]
Garcia-Vega, M., 2006, “Does Technological Diversification Promote Innovation?: An Empirical Analysis for European Firms”, Research Policy, 35(2), 230~246.
[20]
Faurel, L., Q. Li, D. Shanthikumar and S.H. Teoh, 2021, “Bringing Innovation to Fruition: Insights from New Trademarks”, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 59(2), pp.474~520.
[21]
Hauser, J. R. and S. M. Shugan, 1983, “Defensive Marketing Strategies”, Marketing Science, 2(4), pp.319~360.
[22]
Hoberg, G. and G.Phillips, 2010, “Product Market Synergies and Competition in Mergers and Acquisitions: A Text-based Analysis”, The Review of Financial Studies, 23(10), pp.3773~3811.
[23]
Hughes, J. S. and S. Pae, 2015, “Discretionary Disclosure, Spillovers, and Competition”, Review of Accounting Studies, 20, pp.319~342.
[24]
Koh, P.S. ,and D.M. Reeb, 2015, “Missing R&D”, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 60(1), pp.73~94.
[25]
Kothari S. P., Li X and Short J E, 2009, “The Effect of Disclosures by Management, Analysts, and Business Press on Cost of Capital, Return Volatility, and Analyst Forecasts: A Study Using Content Analysis”, The Accounting Review, 84(5), pp.1639~1670.
[26]
Leary, M.T. and M.R. Roberts, 2014, “Do Peer Firms Affect Corporate Financial Policy?”, The Journal of Finance, 69(1), pp.139~178.
[27]
Leiponen, A. E., 2008, “Competing through Cooperation:The Organization of Standard Setting in Wireless Telecommunications”, Management Science, 54(11), pp.1904~1919.
[28]
Manski, C. F., 1993, “Identification of Endogenous Social Effects: The Reflection Problem”, The Review of Economic Studies, 60(3), pp.531~542.
[29]
Reinganum, J. F., 1983, “Uncertain Innovation and the Persistence of Monopoly”, The American Economic Review, 73(4), pp.741~748.
[30]
Romer, P.M., 1990, “Endogenous Technological Change”, Journal of Political Economy, 98 (5, Part 2), pp.S71~S102
[31]
Samiee, S. and K. Roth, 1992, “The Influence of Global Marketing Standardization on Performance”, Journal of Marketing, 56(2), pp.1~17.
[32]
Seo, H., 2021, “Peer Effects in Corporate Disclosure Decisions”, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 71(1), pp.101364.
[33]
Shapiro C. and H.R. Varian, 1999, “Information Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy”, Harvard Business Press.
[34]
Spulber, D.F., 2013, “Innovation Economics: The Interplay among Technology Standards, Competitive Conduct, and Economic Performance”, Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 9(4), pp.777~825.
[35]
Tseng, K. and R.I. Zhong, 2024, “Standing on the Shoulders of Giants: Financial Reporting Comparability and Knowledge Accumulation”, Journal of Accounting and Economics, pp.101685.
[36]
Waguespack, D. M. and L. Fleming, 2009, “Scanning the Commons? Evidence on the Benefits to Startups Participating in Open Standards Development”, Management Science, 55(2), pp.210~223.
[37]
Wright, C., A. Sturdy and N. Wylie, 2012, “Management Innovation through Standardization: Consultants as Standardizers of Organizational Practice”, Research Policy, 41(3), pp.652~662.
[38]
Zhang, M., Y. Wang and Q. Zhao, 2020, “Does Participating in the Standards-setting Process Promote Innovation? Evidence from China”, China Economic Review, 63,pp.101532.
[39]
Zhang, Y., 2024, “Corporate R&D Investments Following Competitors' Voluntary Disclosures: Evidence from the Drug Development Process”, Journal of Accounting Research, 62(1), pp.335~373.