Economic Competitive Growth and Determinants of the Formation Mechanism of Regional Inflation Differentials in China: Analysis of the Penn-Balassa-Samuelson Effect Based on Spatial Econometrics
Summary:
Inter-regional inflation differentials within an economy are affected by multiple factors, such as the effectiveness of monetary policy and the coordinated development of regional economies, and have been a focus of research since the establishment of the euro. The prevailing research method in this field is based on the theory of the Balassa-Samuelson effect (hereinafter referred to the BS effect), which was originally used in the dichotomy framework as the basis of a cross-border real exchange rates model. However, it remains under debate whether BS effect theory can be applied within a country, and whether there are new features within a country is also highly noteworthy. Regional inflation differentials are particularly important for a large country like China, which has undergone rapid economic transformation and upgrading in recent decades. Moreover, inter-regional competitive growth is recognized as an important driving force of China's “economic miracle”. Thus, the Penn-BS effect paradigm based on the perspective of growth and productivity is especially relevant for analyzing the inflation differentials between regions in China. However, very few studies take this perspective, and there are also some problems that need to be clarified. In this study, we adopt the Penn-BS effect analysis paradigm for the first time to examine the basic pattern, the fluctuation sources, and then the driving forces of inflation differentials. We use the spatial econometric model to study the mechanism of formation of medium-to long-term inflation differentials within China and find that the theoretical core of the BS effect applies to the inflation differentials within China. However, we also find that the theoretical core of the BS effect shows new characteristics, which may be related to the breaking of the original dichotomy framework under the servitization trend of manufacturing. We begin by examining the basic pattern the regional inflation differentials in China from the perspective of economic growth and analyzing whether the Penn effect or the Kaldor effect applies to China. Based on the inflation and growth data of 28 provinces in China from 1992 to 2019, we find that the inflation differentials within China follow the basic law of the Penn effect. We adopt the amount of Jinshi in each region during the Ming and Qing dynasties as an instrumental variable and perform a robustness test, and find that the abovementioned conclusions remain unchanged. Whether the Penn effect seen in China can be explained by BS effect theory depends on the structural sources of the inflation differentials. We adopt the variance decomposition method of Betts and Kehoe (2008) and use two indicators—variance and mean squared error—to decompose the contributions of different factors in the fluctuation sources of the inflation differentials within China. We find that deviations from the law of one price and the relative price effect are both important sources. The former is more important than the latter in most cases, and spatial adjacency also has a highly significant impact the inflation differentials. In addition, this result shows that the traditional paradigm of BS effect analysis remains necessary within an economy. Moreover, the prominent position of the deviation from the law of one price is also a paradox in the analysis of the BS effect. Given the significant spatial correlation of inter-provincial inflation in China, we establish a spatial Durbin model to analyze whether the core of BS effect theory, namely the positive correlation between inter-departmental relative productivity and inter-departmental relative price, applies within China. For the first time, we use a spatial weight matrix that is constructed using inter-regional trade and geographic distance data. We find that relative productivity in a region has a significant and positive direct effect on the local internal real exchange rate, indicating the presence of the BS effect, but has a negative spatial spillover effect. In terms of spatial heterogeneity, the western region's relative productivity has the greatest direct effect, and negative spatial spillover effects mainly occur between regions with strong heterogeneity. We also find that the greater the division of labor markets among regions, the stronger is the BS effect, which means that the existence of obstacles to labor mobility underpin the occurrence of the BS effect within a country. Furthermore, we find that there is a negative relationship between relative productivity and overall inflation rate, which represents another paradox. However, this finding is consistent with the domestic BS effect theory proposed by Changjiang and Sheng (2021), which holds that the dichotomy framework is no longer in line with the characteristics of modern service industries. Instead, it is necessary to divide the service industry into the productive service industry and the life service industry, and then adopt a three-sector framework. The key conclusions of this theory are confirmed in this paper and offer a preliminary explanation for the two paradoxes mentioned above. That is, these paradoxes can be considered to reflect the new characteristics of the BS effect within a country and represent the main mechanism of formation of regional inflation differentials in China.
杨长江, 李博. 竞争性增长与中国地区间通货膨胀差异形成机制 ——基于空间计量的“宾大—巴拉萨—萨缪尔森效应”分析[J]. 金融研究, 2023, 517(7): 21-39.
YANG Changjiang, LI Bo. Economic Competitive Growth and Determinants of the Formation Mechanism of Regional Inflation Differentials in China: Analysis of the Penn-Balassa-Samuelson Effect Based on Spatial Econometrics. Journal of Financial Research, 2023, 517(7): 21-39.
[1]程名望和刘金典,2019,《中国劳动力省际转移特征及其影响因素——基于博弈论视角》,《人口与经济》第2期,第28~34页。 [2]邓飞和柯文进,2020,《异质型人力资本与经济发展——基于空间异质性的实证研究》,《统计研究》第2期,第93~104页。 [3]郭峰和洪占卿,2013,《贸易开放、地区市场规模与中国省际通胀波动》,《金融研究》第3期,第73~86页。 [4]姬广林,2017,《中国地区通胀的空间特征与人口年龄结构关联性研究——基于动态空间面板模型》,《国际金融研究》第4期,第32~43页。 [5]王恕立和胡宗彪,2012,《中国服务业分行业生产率变迁及异质性考察》,《经济研究》第4期,第15~27页。 [6]吴建利和刘晓辉,2020,《收入差距与巴拉萨—萨缪尔森效应——基于空间计量的实证分析及机制检验》,《国际金融研究》第10期,第3~13页。 [7]徐现祥、周吉梅和舒元,2007,《中国省区三次产业资本存量估计》,《统计研究》第5期,第6~13页。 [8]杨继生,2009,《通胀预期、流动性过剩与中国通货膨胀的动态性质》,《经济研究》第1期,第106~117页。 [9]杨长江,2014,《“巴拉萨—萨缪尔森效应”研究》,复旦大学出版社2014年10月第一版。 [10]杨长江和徐盛,2021,《长安缘何米贵?中国地区间相对价格水平研究》,《世界经济》第8期,第55~81页。 [11]余泳泽,2017,《异质性视角下中国省际全要素生产率再估算: 1978—2012》,《经济学(季刊)》第3期,第1051~1072页。 [12]喻旭兰、李洋和张欣欣,2014,《我国通货膨胀区域差异的实证研究》,《统计研究》第2期,第55~60页。 [13]张军,2005,《中国经济发展:为增长而竞争》,《世界经济文汇》第4期,第101~105页。 [14]张军、吴桂英和张吉鹏,2004,《中国省际物质资本存量估算: 1952—2000》,《经济研究》第10期,第35~44页。 [15]赵进文和苏明政,2014,《劳动力市场分割、金融一体化与巴拉萨—萨缪尔森效应——基于省际面板平滑转换模型的检验》,《金融研究》第1期,第16~28页。 [16]赵文哲和周业安,2009,《基于省际面板的财政支出与通货膨胀关系研究》,《经济研究》第10期,第48~60页。 [17]周黎安,2007,《中国地方官员的晋升锦标赛模式研究》,《经济研究》第7期,第36~50页。 [18]周亚军,2011,《实际汇率、通货膨胀与巴拉萨—萨缪尔森效应假说——基于中国省际面板数据的实证检验》,《财经理论与实践》第2期,第8~12+110页。 [19]Altissimo, F., P. Benigno and D. R. Palenzuela, 2005, “Long-run Determinants of Inflation Differentials Within a Monetary Union”, NBER Working Papers, No. 11473. [20]Anselin, L., 2002, “Under the Hood Issues in the Specification and Interpretation of Spatial Regression Models”, Agricultural Economics, 27(3):247~267. [21]Arnold, I.and C. J. M. Kool, 2004, “The Role of Inflation Differentials in Regional Adjustment: Evidence from the United States”, Working Papers 04-13,Utrecht School of Economics. [22]Balassa, B., 1964, “The Purchasing-Power Parity Doctrine, A Reappraisal”, Journal of Political Economy, 72(6):584~596. [23]Betts, C. M.and T. J. Kehoe, 2008, “Real Exchange Rate Movements and The Relative Price of Non-traded Goods”, NBER Working Papers,No.14437. [24]Cheung, Y. W. and E. Fujii, 2014, “The Penn Effect Within a Country, Evidence from Japan”, Oxford Economic Papers, 66(4):1070~1089. [25]De Gregorio, J., A. Giovannini and H. C. Wolf, 1994, “International Evidence on Tradables and Nontradables Inflation”, European Economic Review, 38(6):1225~1244. [26]de Haan, J., 2010,“Inflation differentials in the Euro Area: A survey”, in de Haan J. and H. Berger, The European Central Bank at Ten, Springer. [27]Deaton, A.and O. Dupriez, 2011, “Spatial Price Differences within Large Countries”, Princeton University Working Paper, No. 1321. [28]Dixon, R.and A. P, Thirwall, 1975, “A Model of Regional Growth-Rate Difference on Kaldorian Lines”, Oxford Economic Papers, 27(2):201~214. [29]ECB, 2003, “Inflation Differentials in the Euro Area: Potential Causes and Policy Implications”, European Central Bank. [30]Engel, C., 1999, “Accounting for US Real Exchange Rate Changes”, Journal of Political Economy, 107(3):507~538. [31]Gerlach, S. and W. S. Peng, 2006, “Output Gaps and Inflation in Mainland China”, China Economic Review, 17(2):210~225. [32]Goldsmith-Pinkham, P., I. Sorkin and H. Swift, 2020, “Bartik Instruments, What, When, Why, and How”, American Economic Review, 110(8):2586~2624. [33]Guillaumont Jeanneney, S. and P. Hua, 2002, “ The Balassa-Samuelson Effect and Inflation in the Chinese Provinces”,China Economic Review, 13(2-3):134~160. [34]Guo, Q. and S. Hall, 2010, “A Test of the Balassa-Samuelson Effect Applied to Chinese Regional Data”, Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting, 13(2): 57~78. [35]Kaldor, N., 1970, “ The Case for Regional Policies”, Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 17(3):337~348. [36]LeSage, J. and R. K. Pace, 2009, Introduction to Spatial Econometrics, CRC Press. [37]Mehrotra, A., T. Peltonen and A. S. Rivera, 2010, “Modelling Inflation in China—A Regional Perspective”, China Economic Review, 21(2):237~255. [38]Nagayasu, J., 2017, “Regional Inflation, Spatial Locations and the Balassa-Samuelson Effect, Evidence from Japan”, Urban Studies, 54(6):1482~1499. [39]Nagayasu, J. and N. Inakura, 2009, “PPP, Further Evidence from Japanese Regional Data”, International Review of Economics and Finance, 18(3):419~427. [40]Ohr, R., 2009, “European Monetary Union at Ten: Had the German Maastricht Critics Been Wrong? ” University of Goettingen Departmental Discussion Papers,No.141. [41]Rabanal, P., 2009, “Inflation Differentials between Spain and the EMU, A DSGE Perspective”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 41(6):1141~1166. [42]Ricci, L. A., G. M. Milesi-Ferretti and J. Lee, 2013, “Real Exchange Rates and Fundamentals, A Cross-Country Perspective”,Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 45 (5):845~865. [43]Samuelson, P.A., 1964, “Theoretical Notes on Trade Problems”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 46:145~154. [44]Samuelson, P. A., 1994, “Facets of Balassa-Samuelson Thirty Years Later”, Review of International Economics, 2(3): 201~226. [45]Vaona, A. and G. Ascari, 2012, “Regional Inflation Persistence, Evidence From Italy”, Regional Studies, 46(4):509~523. [46]Wincenciak, L., 2008, “Balassa-Samuelson Effect in Poland, Is Real Convergence a Threat to Nominal One?”, Ekonomia. Rynek, Gospodarka, Społeczeństwo, 20:112~130. [47]Young, A., 2000, “The Razor's Edge: Distortions and Incremental Reform in the People's Republic of China”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4):1091~1135.