Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2021, Vol. 496 Issue (10): 78-97    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
人力资本偏向金融部门如何影响实体经济增长?
刘贯春, 司登奎, 刘芳
中山大学岭南学院,广东广州 510275;
青岛大学经济学院,山东青岛 266061;
上海社会科学院世界经济研究所,上海 200020
Does Human Capital in the Financial Sector Affect Real Economic Growth in China?
LIU Guanchun, SI Dengkui, LIU Fang
Lingnan College, Sun Yat-sen University;
School of Economics, Qingdao University;
Institute for the World Economy, Shanghai Academy of Social Sciences
下载:  PDF (1179KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 通过构建一个包含银行和生产性企业的两部门增长模型,本文系统考察人力资本偏向金融部门如何影响实体经济增长,并利用2008年中国经济普查数据、2003-2015年地级市数据及2011-2013年中国工业企业数据开展实证检验。理论分析表明,人力资本在金融部门与实体部门之间的配置结构对实体经济增长存在两种效应,依次为资本“挤入”效应和创新“挤出”效应,进而导致人力资本配置情况与实体经济增长率之间呈现倒“U”形关系。随后,计量结果为上述理论推断提供了系列经验证据,且机制检验证实人力资本配置到金融部门有助于促进信贷规模扩张。特别地,反事实框架的测算结果显示,人力资本有效配置将提升实体经济增长率约0.45%,而且贡献率随经济发展更加凸显。本文结论表明,应理性看待人力资本向金融部门的不断聚集,不以简单线性关系进行判断,要综合权衡资本“挤入”效应和创新“挤出”效应的相对重要性。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
刘贯春
司登奎
刘芳
关键词:  金融部门  实体经济增长  人力资本配置  倒“U”形关系    
Summary:  The fundamental purpose of the financial sector is to serve the real economy. Currently, China's economic development is characterized by a “cold” real economy and a “hot” virtual economy. The financial sector is favored by social elites, while the real sector exhibits a sluggish trend. The mainstream explanation for this disconnect is that human capital has been overallocated to the financial sector, stifling innovation in the real sector and thus leading to a decline in real economic growth. However, given the information asymmetry between creditors and borrowers, increasing human capital in the financial sector also helps eliminate credit contract frictions,and result in credit expansion, which promotes real economic growth. To provide theoretical and practical reference for deepening financial supply-side structural reform and realizing an innovation-driven growth regime, this paper investigates how the allocation of human capital between the financial and real sectors affects real economic growth in China.
In theory, the financial sector's human capital has ambiguous effects on real economic growth. On the one hand, it hinders real economic growth through the following channels: (i) crowding out labor and capital in the real sector; (ii) transferring profit from the real sector, weakening entrepreneurship, and reducing the intrinsic incentives of productive activities; and (iii) lowering the overall entrepreneurial ability. On the other hand, it promotes real economic growth through the following channels: (i) strengthening the ability of the financial sector to absorb social deposits via financial product innovation and industrial competition; (ii) alleviating the information asymmetry between creditors and borrowers and accurately identifying the ability of firms to repay loans; and (iii) improving the allocation of credit among firms with different financing constraints.
This paper constructs a two-sector growth model consisting of banks and firms to investigate how the financial sector's human capital affects real economic growth. It then tests the model using the 2008 Chinese Economic Census dataset and data from prefecture-level cities from 2003 to 2015. The theoretical analysis shows that there is an inverse U-type relationship between human capital in the financial sector and real economic growth which is driven by capital crowd-in and innovation crowd-out effects. A series of empirical analyses supports the model's predications. In particular, our simple counterfactual calculation suggests that the real economic growth rate will increase by about 0.45% when human capital is efficiently allocated between the financial and real sectors, and the contribution increases as China's economy grows. This paper obtains similar findings using the Chinese Industrial Database over the 2011-2013 period and confirms that the financial sector's human capital increases a firm's access to external financing and reduces capital misallocation among firms.
In sum, these findings demonstrate that increasing human capital in the financial sector does not absolutely promote or inhibit real economic growth,suggesting that there is an optimal allocation threshold of human capital between the financial and real sectors. Therefore, to maintain long-term and high-quality economic growth, it is important to optimize human capital allocation. This paper's theoretical analysis and empirical findings have important policy implications. First, because talented employees are drawn to the financial sector for its high salaries, policymakers should improve modes of income distribution. Second, it is essential to restrict the blind expansion of the financial sector and strengthen its functions of providing financial services to the real sector. The “financial sector transfers 1.5 trillion yuan of profits to the real sector” policy implemented in 2020 in response to the COVID-19 epidemic not only helps reduce the financing cost of firms, but may also help to optimize the allocation of human capital.
This paper makes three contributions to the literature. First, it is the first to examine how human capital in the financial sector affects China's real economic growth. Other studies focus on the growth effects of the allocation of human capital between rent-seeking and productive sectors, whereas this paper explores the effect of human capital allocation between the financial and real sectors. Second, this paper examines the influence of human capital allocation in the financial sector on real economic growth and the mechanism that underlies this influence. Although there are several related theoretical studies, this paper uses empirical evidence to confirm that the financial sector's human capital is conducive to expanding credit scale. Third, this paper enriches the understanding of the link between financial development and economic growth. Previous studies focus on the scale expansion and structural adjustment of the financial system, whereas this paper adopts the perspective of human capital allocation, which provides a new explanation for the inverse U-type relationship between financial development and economic growth.
Keywords:  Financial Sector    Real Economic Growth    Human Capital Allocation    Inverse U-type Relationship
JEL分类号:  D24   J24   O41  
基金资助: * 本文感谢国家自然科学基金青年项目(72003116)、上海市“晨光计划”项目(19CG40)、“泰山学者”专项工程经费(taqn202103054)和山东省自然科学基金青年项目(ZR2019QG010)的资助。感谢匿名审稿人的宝贵意见,文责自负。
通讯作者:  司登奎,经济学博士,副教授,青岛大学经济学院,E-mail:sidkfinance@163.com.   
作者简介:  刘贯春,经济学博士,副教授,中山大学岭南学院,E-mail:liuguanchun1@126.com.
刘 芳,经济学博士,助理研究员,上海社会科学院世界经济研究所,E-mail:liufang@ sass.org.cn.
引用本文:    
刘贯春, 司登奎, 刘芳. 人力资本偏向金融部门如何影响实体经济增长?[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 496(10): 78-97.
LIU Guanchun, SI Dengkui, LIU Fang. Does Human Capital in the Financial Sector Affect Real Economic Growth in China?. Journal of Financial Research, 2021, 496(10): 78-97.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2021/V496/I10/78
[1] 李静、楠玉和刘霞辉,2017,《中国经济稳增长难题:人力资本错配及其解决途径》,《经济研究》第3期,第18~31页。
[2] 李世刚和尹恒,2017,《政府-企业间人才配置与经济增长——基于中国地级市数据的经验研究》,《经济研究》第4期,第78~91页。
[3] 林毅夫、孙希芳和姜烨,2009,《经济发展中的最优金融结构理论初探》,《经济研究》第8期,第4~17页。
[4] 刘贯春、张军和丰超,2017,《金融体制改革与经济效率提升:来自省级面板数据的经验分析》,《管理世界》第7期,第9~22页。
[5] 张成思和刘贯春,2015,《经济增长进程中金融结构的边际效应演化分析》,《经济研究》第12期,第84~99页。
[6] 张杰、吴书凤和金岳,2021,《中国金融扩张下的本土企业创新效应——基于倒U型关系的一个解释》,《金融研究》第4期,第55~72页。
[7] 中国经济增长前沿课题组,2014,《中国经济增长的低效率冲击与减速治理》,《经济研究》第12期,第4~17页。
[8] 庄毓敏、储青青和马勇,2020,《金融发展、企业创新与经济增长》,《金融研究》第4期,第11~30页。
[9] Acemoglu, D, 1995. “Reward Structures and the Allocation of Talent”, European Economic Review, 39(1): 17~33.
[10] Aghion, P., A. Banerjee and T. Piketty. 1999. “Dualism and Macroeconomic Volatility”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4): 1359~1397.
[11] Benhabib, J. and M. Spiegel, 1994. “The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate Cross-Country Data”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 34(2): 143~173.
[12] Brandt, L., J. V. Biesebroeck and Y. Zhang, 2012. “Creative Accounting or Creative Destruction? Firm-Level Productivity Growth in Chinese Manufacturing”, Journal of Development Economics, 97(2): 339~351.
[13] Cahuc, P. and E. Challe, 2012. “Produce or Speculate? Asset Bubbles, Occupational Choice, and Efficiency”, International Economic Review, 53(4): 1105~1131.
[14] Cai, H. and Q. Liu, 2009. “Competition and Corporate Tax Avoidance: Evidence from Chinese Industrial Firms”, Economic Journal, 119(537): 764~795.
[15] Cai, X., Y. Lu, M. Wu and L. Yu, 2016. “Does Environmental Regulation Drive Away Inbound Foreign Direct Investment? Evidence from a Quasi-Natural Experiment in China”, Journal of Development Economics, 126(12): 73~85.
[16] Cecchetti, S. G. and E. Kharroubi, 2012. “Reassessing the Impact of Finance on Growth”, BIS Working Paper No.381.
[17] Cecchetti, S. G. and E. Kharroubi, 2019. “Why Does Financial Sector Growth Crowd Out Real Economic Growth?”, Manchester School, 87(S1): 1~28.
[18] Chetty, R., A. Looney and K. Kroft, 2009. “Salience and Taxation: Theory and Evidence”, American Economic Review, 99(4): 1145~1177.
[19] Gennaioli, N., A. Shleifer and R. Vishny, 2014. “Finance and the Preservation of Wealth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(3):1221~1254
[20] Murphy, K. M., A. Shleifer and R. W. Vishny, 1991. “The Allocation of Talent: Implications for Growth”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2): 503~530.
[21] Murphy, K. M., A. Shleifer and R. W. Vishny, 1993. “Why Is Rent-Seeking So Costly to Growth?”, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 83(2): 409~414.
[22] Olley, G. S. and A. Pakes, 1996. “The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry”, Econometrica, 46(6): 1263-1297.
[23] Pagano, M, 1993. “Financial Markets and Growth: An Overview”, European Economic Review, 37(2-3): 613~622.
[24] Philippon, T, 2010. “Financiers versus Engineers: Should the Financial Sector Be Taxed or Subsidized?”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2(3): 158~182.
[25] Philippon, T. and A. Reshef, 2012. “Wages and Human Capital in the U.S. Finance Industry: 1909-2006”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(4): 1551~1609.
[26] Rajan, R. G. and L. Zingales, 1998. “Financial Dependence and Growth”, American Economic Review, 88(3): 559~586.
[27] Zheng, J., A. Bigsten and A. Hu, 2009. “Can China's Growth Be Sustained? A Productivity Perspective”, World Development, 37(4): 874~888.
[1] 李丽芳, 谭政勋, 叶礼贤. 改进的效率测算模型、影子银行与中国商业银行效率[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 496(10): 98-116.
[2] 朱宁, 刘伟其, 于之倩, 王兵. 中国银行业结构性全要素生产率增长研究[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 493(7): 1-18.
[3] 公衍磊, 邓辛, 杨金强. 全要素生产率、产能利用率与企业金融资源配置——基于中国上市企业委托贷款公告数据的经验分析[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 481(7): 57-74.
[4] 丁宁, 任亦侬, 左颖. 绿色信贷政策得不偿失还是得偿所愿?——基于资源配置视角的PSM-DID成本效率分析[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 478(4): 112-130.
[5] 蔡卫星. 银行业市场结构对企业生产率的影响——来自工业企业的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 466(4): 39-55.
[6] 王兵, 肖文伟. 环境规制与中国外商直接投资变化——基于DEA多重分解的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 464(2): 59-77.
[7] 朱宁, 梁林, 沈智扬, 杜文洁. 经济新常态背景下中国商业银行内生性效率变化及分解[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 457(7): 108-123.
[8] 祝树金, 赵玉龙. 资源错配与企业的出口行为——基于中国工业企业数据的经验研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 49-64.
[9] 罗知, 张川川. 信贷扩张、房地产投资与制造业部门的资源配置效率[J]. 金融研究, 2015, 421(7): 60-75.
[10] 陈经伟, 姜能鹏. 中国OFDI技术创新效应的传导机制——基于资本要素市场扭曲视角的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 482(8): 74-92.
[1] 王曦, 朱立挺, 王凯立. 我国货币政策是否关注资产价格?——基于马尔科夫区制转换BEKK多元GARCH模型[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 1 -17 .
[2] 刘勇政, 李岩. 中国的高速铁路建设与城市经济增长[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 18 -33 .
[3] 况伟大, 王琪琳. 房价波动、房贷规模与银行资本充足率[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 34 -48 .
[4] 祝树金, 赵玉龙. 资源错配与企业的出口行为——基于中国工业企业数据的经验研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 49 -64 .
[5] 陈德球, 陈运森, 董志勇. 政策不确定性、市场竞争与资本配置[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 65 -80 .
[6] 牟敦果, 王沛英. 中国能源价格内生性研究及货币政策选择分析[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 81 -95 .
[7] 高铭, 江嘉骏, 陈佳, 刘玉珍. 谁说女子不如儿郎?——P2P投资行为与过度自信[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 96 -111 .
[8] 吕若思, 刘青, 黄灿, 胡海燕, 卢进勇. 外资在华并购是否改善目标企业经营绩效?——基于企业层面的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 112 -127 .
[9] 姜军, 申丹琳, 江轩宇, 伊志宏. 债权人保护与企业创新[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 128 -142 .
[10] 刘莎莎, 孔高文. 信息搜寻、个人投资者交易与股价联动异象——基于股票送转的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 143 -157 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1