Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2021, Vol. 489 Issue (3): 1-17    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
投资潮涌、双重金融摩擦与货币政策传导——转型时期货币政策的结构调控功能探究
战明华, 李帅, 姚耀军, 吴周恒
广东外语外贸大学金融学院,广东广州 510016;
浙江工商大学金融学院,浙江杭州 310018
Investment Surges, Dual Financial Frictions,and Monetary Policy Transmission: Demystifying the Structural Adjustment Function of Monetary Policy During the Economic Transition
ZHAN Minghua, LI Shuai, YAO Yaojun, WU Zhouheng
School of Finance, Guangdong University of Foreign Studies;
School of Finance, Zhejiang Gongshang University
下载:  PDF (550KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 在银行融资与企业融资两大市场均存在金融摩擦的条件下,经济转型时期的“投资潮涌”蕴含重要货币经济学含义。以货币政策调控行业过剩产能为例,本文为解释转型时期中国货币政策结构调控功能构建一个理论分析框架,并对相关理论假说进行实证检验。经验证据显示:当不同产能过剩行业的企业在抵押能力信息传递上存在系统异质性时,货币政策具有显著产能调控功能,而调控作用的大小与企业产权结构以及货币政策工具类型有关。通过融合“投资潮涌”与BGG理论,本文将BGG理论中的货币政策效应异质性从企业层面拓展至行业层面,进而揭示了传统非结构性货币政策在转型经济背景下何以具有结构调控功能的理论机制。结论表明,进一步夯实金融市场微观基础,协同推进实体经济供给侧结构性改革与利率市场化改革,对于健全价格型货币政策调控体系至关重要。文章也为通过进一步完善和创新分类调控政策思路,实现灵活精准、合理适度的货币政策操作路径提供了政策启示。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
战明华
李帅
姚耀军
吴周恒
关键词:  货币政策  结构调控  投资潮涌  金融摩擦    
Summary:  Investment surges are a typical phenomenon during China's current transitional period, as Justin Lin (2007) observes. Investment may systemically lean toward certain industries, due to either market distortions or government interventions. Investment leanings can lead to capital misallocation and excess capacity in some industries. To correct this imbalance, monetary policies have sometimes been successfully applied to de-capacitize these industries. Theoretically, however, monetary policy does not have structural adjustment functions, even when it is non-neutral in the long run. Therefore, explaining the industrial structural adjustment effects of Chinese monetary policy remains a great puzzle.
In this paper, we explain this puzzle from the perspectives of heterogeneous capacity features and property rights differences between enterprises in China. We construct a theoretical model with a dual financial frictions mechanism in the credit market to illustrate the de-capacitizing effects of monetary policy on excess industrial capacity. The dual financial frictions are the collateral constraint on enterprise and the leverage constraint on banks. The monetary policy transmission is marginally distorted by systematic differences in the balance sheet features of excess capacity industries and the property rights differences of enterprises. We find first that the investments of excess capacity enterprises are more strongly repressed under contractionary monetary policies. Second, state-owned enterprises are less affected by contractionary monetary policies, as they possess better collaterals than private enterprises do. Third, quantitative monetary policy tools are more effective than price-based monetary policy tools.
We use macroeconomic aggregate data and A-share listed firm-level panel data from 2006 Q1 to 2017 Q3 to empirically verify the theoretical hypotheses. We find first that monetary policy has a significant de-capacitizing function. Second, the de-capacitizing function of monetary policy is mainly effective for excess capacity private enterprises. Third, quantitative monetary policy tools are more effective than price-based tools. Finally, expansionary and contractionary operations have asymmetric effects. State-owned enterprises are affected only by expansion. Private enterprises are affected by both expansion and contraction, and are more sensitive to contraction.
Our paper theoretically and empirically verifies that monetary policy has long-term industrial structural adjustment functions in China. It can have such functions when financial frictions and distortions prevail in the financial market, and when enterprises are heterogeneous in balance sheet features and in their ability to obtain external financing in the credit market.
Our work contributes to the literature in the following ways. First, we document and explain the long-term structural effects of monetary policy in transitional economies with financial frictions and institutional barriers. This is different from the traditional conclusion of monetary theories and studies regarding developed economies (Clarida and Gertler, 1999; Walsh, 2003). Second, our dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model clarifies the mechanisms of the de-capacitizing functions of monetary policy, identifying an interest rate channel and a credit channel. These channels fill the mechanism analysis gap in related literature on the de-capacitizing functions of monetary policy (Wei, 1993; Song, 1997; Zhou, 2004). Third, we discuss the effectiveness of interest rate tools and quantitative tools such as reserve requirements. Our paper therefore sheds light on the greater effectiveness of quantitatively based monetary policy tools in addressing structural problems.
Our research has important policy implications. First, different monetary policy tools have different structural adjustment effects. This implies that monetary authorities should choose and apply different tools according to their best marginal effects. Second, the structural adjustment functions of regular monetary policy tools should be considered in practice alongside other structural monetary policy tools. This is consistent with the creative application of monetary management identified by the communiqué of the fifth plenary session of the 19th Central Committee of the Communist Party of China. Third, the full functioning of interest rate marketization depends on the deep reform of microstructure financial markets due to microeconomic agents' heterogeneous features (Xu, 2018). Finally, the coordinated promotion of real economy supply-side structural reforms, interest rate marketization reform, and the construction of a high-level socialist market economy system are essential to a sound price-based monetary policy system.
Keywords:  Monetary Policy    Structural Functions    Investment Surges    Dual Financial Frictions
JEL分类号:  E42   E44   E52  
基金资助: * 本文感谢国家社会科学基金重点项目(19AJY017、20AJY026)、国家自然科学基金项目(71703029)、教育部人文社科重点研究基地重大项目(10JJD790031)和广东省自然科学基金项目(2019A1515011765)的资助。感谢匿名审稿人的宝贵意见,文责自负。
通讯作者:  吴周恒,经济学博士,副教授,广东外语外贸大学金融学院,E-mail:wuzhouheng 1984@163.com.   
作者简介:  战明华,管理学博士,教授,广东外语外贸大学金融学院,E-mail:zhanmheco@163.com.
李 帅,金融学博士研究生,广东外语外贸大学金融学院,E-mail:alishuai2010@126.com.
姚耀军,管理学博士,教授,浙江工商大学金融学院,E-mail:yaoyaojun@163.com.
引用本文:    
战明华, 李帅, 姚耀军, 吴周恒. 投资潮涌、双重金融摩擦与货币政策传导——转型时期货币政策的结构调控功能探究[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 489(3): 1-17.
ZHAN Minghua, LI Shuai, YAO Yaojun, WU Zhouheng. Investment Surges, Dual Financial Frictions,and Monetary Policy Transmission: Demystifying the Structural Adjustment Function of Monetary Policy During the Economic Transition. Journal of Financial Research, 2021, 489(3): 1-17.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2021/V489/I3/1
[1] 国务院发展研究中心课题组,2015,《当前我国产能过剩的特征、风险及对策研究》,《管理世界》第4期,第1~10页。
[2] 韩国高、高铁梅、王立国、齐鹰飞和王晓姝,2011,《中国制造业产能过剩的测度、波动及成因研究》,《经济研究》第12期,第18~31页。
[3] 林毅夫,2007,《潮涌现象与发展中国家宏观经济理论的重新构建》,《经济研究》第1期,第126~131页。
[4] 林毅夫、巫和懋和邢亦青,2010,《“潮涌现象”与产能过剩的形成机制》,《经济研究》第10期,第4~19页。
[5] 欧阳志刚和薛龙,2017,《新常态下多种货币政策工具对特殊企业的定向调节效应》,《管理世界》第2期,第53~66页。
[6] 彭俞超和方意,2016,《结构性货币政策、产业结构升级与经济稳定》,《经济研究》第7期,第29~42页。
[7] 宋海林,1997,《运用信贷政策调整经济结构的若干思考》,《金融研究》第12期,第1~7页。
[8] 韦超,1993,《发挥金融政策在产业结构调整中的作用》,《金融研究》第9期,第12~16页。
[9] 徐朝阳和周念利,2015,《市场结构内生变迁与产能过剩治理》,《经济研究》第2期, 第75~87页。
[10] 徐涛,2007,《中国货币政策的行业效应分析》,《世界经济》第2期,第23~31页。
[11] 周逢民,2004,《论货币政策的结构调整职能》,《金融研究》第7期,第51~56页。
[12] Agénor, P. R. and P. J. Montiel. 2007. “Credit Market Imperfections and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism. Part II: Flexible Exchange Rates”, Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research Discussion Paper Series 87, Economics, The Univeristy of Manchester.
[13] Barro, R.J. 1996. “Inflation and Growth”, Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis Review, 78: 153~169.
[14] Bernanke, B. S. 1993. “Credit in the Macroeconomy”, Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review, 18(1):50~70.
[15] Bernanke, B. S. and M. Gertler. 1989. “Agency Costs,Net Worth,and Business Fluctuations”, American Economic Review , 79(1):14~31.
[16] Bernanke, B. S., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1999.“The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework”, Handbook of Macroeconomics, in: Benjamin M. Friedman & Michael Woodford (ed.), 1(12):1341~1393.
[17] Gertler, M. and Kiyotaki, N. 2010. “Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis”, Handbook of Monetary Economics, in: Benjamin M. Friedman & Michael Woodford (ed.), 3(11): 547~599.
[18] Lucas, R.E. 1996. “Nobel Lecture: Monetary Neutrality”, Journal of Political Economy, 104(4):661~682.
[19] Philip Lowe. 2012. “The Changing Structure of the Australian Economy and Monetary Policy”, Address to the Australian industry Group 12th Annual Economic Forum, 2012(3):79~84.
[20] Stiglize, J.E. and A.Weiss. 1981. “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information”, American Economc Review, 71(3):393~410.
[21] Walsh, C. E. 2002. “Economic Structure and Monetary Policy Design”, Working Paper at the EWC/KDI conference.
[22] Walsh, C. E. 2003. “Monetary Theory and Policy” , 2nd edn. Cambridge,MA: MIT Press.
[23] Walsh, C. E. 2004. “Implications of a Changing Economic Structure for the Strategy of Monetary Policy”, Santa Cruz Center for International Economics Working Paper, II (4):297~348.
[1] 董兵兵, 徐慧伦, 谭小芬. 货币政策能够兼顾稳增长与防风险吗?——基于动态随机一般均衡模型的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 490(4): 19-37.
[2] 陆军, 黄嘉. 利率市场化改革与货币政策银行利率传导[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 490(4): 1-18.
[3] 尚玉皇, 赵芮, 董青马. 混频数据信息下的时变货币政策传导行为研究——基于混频 TVP-FAVAR模型[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 487(1): 13-30.
[4] 侯成琪, 黄彤彤. 流动性、银行间市场摩擦与借贷便利类货币政策工具[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 483(9): 78-96.
[5] 庄子罐, 贾红静, 刘鼎铭. 居民风险偏好与中国货币政策的宏观经济效应——基于DSGE模型的数量分析[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 483(9): 40-58.
[6] 马勇, 付莉. “双支柱”调控、政策协调搭配与宏观稳定效应[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 482(8): 1-17.
[7] 黄继承, 姚驰, 姜伊晴, 牟天琦. “双支柱”调控的微观稳定效应研究[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 481(7): 1-20.
[8] 邓路, 刘欢, 侯粲然. 金融资产配置与违约风险:蓄水池效应,还是逐利效应?[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 481(7): 172-189.
[9] 郝大鹏, 王博, 李力. 美联储政策变化、国际资本流动与宏观经济波动[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 481(7): 38-56.
[10] 杜两省, 程博文. 金融摩擦、收入风险与财富不平等[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 481(7): 75-94.
[11] 殷兴山, 易振华, 项燕彪. 总量型和结构型货币政策工具的选择与搭配——基于结构性去杠杆视角下的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 480(6): 60-77.
[12] 张礼卿, 钟茜. 全球金融周期、美国货币政策与“三元悖论”[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 15-33.
[13] 杨继生, 向镜洁. 货币传导异质性与实体经济流动性配置的“马太效应”[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 485(11): 40-57.
[14] 罗煜, 张祎, 朱文宇. 基于银行流动性管理视角的宏观审慎与货币政策协调研究[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 484(10): 19-37.
[15] 谭小芬, 李源, 苟琴. 美国货币政策推升了新兴市场国家非金融企业杠杆率吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 470(8): 38-57.
[1] 王曦, 朱立挺, 王凯立. 我国货币政策是否关注资产价格?——基于马尔科夫区制转换BEKK多元GARCH模型[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 1 -17 .
[2] 刘勇政, 李岩. 中国的高速铁路建设与城市经济增长[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 18 -33 .
[3] 况伟大, 王琪琳. 房价波动、房贷规模与银行资本充足率[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 34 -48 .
[4] 祝树金, 赵玉龙. 资源错配与企业的出口行为——基于中国工业企业数据的经验研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 49 -64 .
[5] 陈德球, 陈运森, 董志勇. 政策不确定性、市场竞争与资本配置[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 65 -80 .
[6] 牟敦果, 王沛英. 中国能源价格内生性研究及货币政策选择分析[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 81 -95 .
[7] 高铭, 江嘉骏, 陈佳, 刘玉珍. 谁说女子不如儿郎?——P2P投资行为与过度自信[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 96 -111 .
[8] 吕若思, 刘青, 黄灿, 胡海燕, 卢进勇. 外资在华并购是否改善目标企业经营绩效?——基于企业层面的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 112 -127 .
[9] 姜军, 申丹琳, 江轩宇, 伊志宏. 债权人保护与企业创新[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 128 -142 .
[10] 刘莎莎, 孔高文. 信息搜寻、个人投资者交易与股价联动异象——基于股票送转的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 143 -157 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1