Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2020, Vol. 480 Issue (6): 60-77    
  论文 本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
总量型和结构型货币政策工具的选择与搭配——基于结构性去杠杆视角下的分析
殷兴山, 易振华, 项燕彪
中国人民银行杭州中心支行,浙江杭州 310001
The Selection and Co-location of Traditional and Structure Monetary Policy Instruments: An Analysis from the Perspective of Structural Leverage Resolving
YIN Xingshan, YI Zhenhua, XIANG Yanbiao
Hangzhou Central Sub-branch, the People's Bank of China
下载:  PDF (1471KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 本文基于我国34类工业行业的年度数据,识别信贷配置偏向特征对结构性杠杆的影响,以及货币政策应对效应的特征事实:信贷偏向的存在导致不同产权性质企业杠杆变化呈现异质性,这种异质性所产生的结构性杠杆现象因经济周期不同阶段而异,传统总量型货币政策工具难以有效解决结构性杠杆问题。为更深入理解这一现象以及结构性去杠杆下货币政策最优选择问题,本文通过构建一个同时包含信贷配置偏向特征、企业杠杆结构变化特征、总量型与结构型货币政策工具影响特征的DSGE模型进行分析,研究结果表明:总量型货币政策数量工具的宽松操作可以有效应对技术冲击下结构性杠杆问题;总量型工具紧缩资金供给,结合结构型工具定向紧缩,是应对成本推动冲击下结构性高杠杆问题的较好选择;当经济面临风险冲击下结构性杠杆和经济下行并存问题时,需要结构型货币政策数量工具和价格工具同时操作,紧缩国企贷款,同时降低民企融资成本。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
殷兴山
易振华
项燕彪
关键词:  信贷偏向  结构性杠杆  结构型货币政策工具    
Summary:  The degree of leverage of China's non-financial corporate sector has risen rapidly since the international financial crisis in 2008. China has the highest leverage level among major global economies, and has the structural characteristic that large and state-owned enterprises have a more significant process of leverage increase than private SMEs. The reasons are complex, but we observe that when the financial structure is dominated by indirect financing, the non-market-oriented interest rate factor weakens the pricing function of financial resources, combined with rigid redemption due to implicit government guarantees, insufficient competition, and serious homogeneity in the financial industry. This results in a credit bias in terms of the property rights and scale discrimination of enterprises during the allocation of credit resources, which leads to a structural mismatch of financial resources and exacerbates the structural leverage problem.
The traditional monetary policy is the monetary aggregate adjustment policy, but this faces a dilemma in dealing with structural leverage. An expansionary monetary policy helps to reduce the interest burden and may stimulate the real sector to obtain more loans. However, a tight monetary policy can restrain the overall leverage level, and thus further exacerbate structural leverage problems. The People's Bank of China recently implemented various structural monetary policy instruments, such as the targeted medium-term lending facility, and monetary policy thus began to show structural features. Thus, making the optimal choice between tradition-oriented and structure-oriented monetary policy instruments, and exerting the structural adjustment effect of the structural monetary policy, have become important variables that must be considered when resolving the policy of structural leverage.
Existing studies analyze the leverage problem and monetary policy responses from various perspectives, and many ideas and methods are proposed. However, the assumptions, leverage characteristics, and policy operation modes of foreign markets are quite different from those of China. Most Chinese studies focus on quantitative descriptive and qualitative analyses, while policy analysis is limited to the responses of the traditional monetary policy. To accurately identify the causes of structural leverage and to understand the effects and mechanisms of different choices of monetary policy instruments on resolving structural leverage, we systematically study this issue from two perspectives: empirical analysis and theoretical analysis.
In our empirical analysis, we identify the relationship among different economic cycles, credit allocation bias, and changes in the leverage structure of enterprises, and examine the effect of traditional monetary policy using a panel regression model based on the annual data of China's 34 industrial sectors. The results indicate that the existence of credit allocation bias leads to heterogeneity in the leverage of enterprises with different property rights, which causes the structural leverage phenomenon to vary in the different stages of the economic cycle, and traditional monetary policy tools cannot easily solve the structural leverage problem. In the theoretical analysis, we combine the asymmetric investment and leverage change effects due to credit allocation bias in our DSGE model to identify the generation mechanism of these effects, and the optimal selection of monetary policy instruments in structural deleveraging. We find that tradition-quantity instrument is a better choice when addressing the structural leverage problem under the shock of technology, and that an appropriate combination of tradition-oriented and structure-oriented instruments is a better choice when addressing structural leverage under a price shock. In addition, if the economy is faced with the co-existence of structural leverage and an economic downturn under the shock of economic risk, structure quantity instruments are necessary to reduce the loans of state-owned enterprises, and structure price instruments are necessary to reduce the loan costs for private enterprises.
Keywords:  Credit Bias    Structural Leverage    Structural Monetary Policy Instrument
JEL分类号:  E20   E58   L20  
作者简介:  殷兴山,经济学博士,高级经济师,中国人民银行杭州中心支行。
项燕彪,数学博士,经济师,中国人民银行杭州中心支行,E-mail:ybxiang321@163.com.
易振华(通讯作者),经济学博士,经济师,中国人民银行杭州中心支行,E-mail:yizhenhua2006@126.com.
引用本文:    
殷兴山, 易振华, 项燕彪. 总量型和结构型货币政策工具的选择与搭配——基于结构性去杠杆视角下的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 480(6): 60-77.
YIN Xingshan, YI Zhenhua, XIANG Yanbiao. The Selection and Co-location of Traditional and Structure Monetary Policy Instruments: An Analysis from the Perspective of Structural Leverage Resolving. Journal of Financial Research, 2020, 480(6): 60-77.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2020/V480/I6/60
[1] 韩国高、高铁梅、王立国、齐鹰飞和王晓姝,2011,《中国制造业产能过剩的测度、波动及成因研究》,《经济研究》第12期,第18~31页。
[2] 胡志鹏,2014,《“稳增长”与“控杠杆”双重目标下的货币当局最优政策设定》,《经济研究》第12期,第60~71+184页。
[3] 何青、钱宗鑫和郭俊杰,2015,《房地产驱动了中国经济周期吗》,《经济研究》第12期,第41~53页。
[4] 纪敏、严宝玉和李宏瑾,2017,《杠杆率结构、水平和金融稳定、理论分析框架和中国经验》,《金融研究》第2期,第11~25页。
[5] 纪洋、王旭、谭语嫣和黄益平,2018,《经济政策不确定性,政府隐性担保与企业杠杆率分化》,《经济学(季刊)》第17卷第2期,第449~470页。
[6] 栗亮和刘元春,2014,《经济波动的变异与中国宏观经济政策框架的重构》,《管理世界》第12期,第38~50+187页。
[7] 刘晓光和张杰平,2016,《中国杠杆率悖论——兼论货币政策“稳增长”和“降杠杆”真的两难吗》,《财贸经济》第8期,第5~19页。
[8] 马贱阳,2011,《结构性货币政策:一般理论和国际经验》,《金融理论与实践》第4期,第111~115页。
[9] 马文涛和魏福成,2011,《基于新凯恩斯动态随机一般均衡模型的季度产出缺口测度》,《管理世界》第5期,第39~65页。
[10] 马建堂、董小君、时红秀、徐杰和马小芳,2016,《中国的杠杆率与系统性金融风险防范》,《财贸经济》第1期,第5~21页。
[11] 马家进,2018,《金融摩擦、企业异质性和中国经济波动——基于DSGE模型的分析》,博士学位论文,浙江大学。
[12] 欧阳志刚和薛龙,2017,《新常态下多种货币政策工具对特征企业的定向调节效应》,《管理世界》第2期,第53~66页。
[13] 彭俞超和方意,2016,《结构性货币政策、产业结构升级与经济稳定》,《经济研究》第7期,第29~42页。
[14] 吴盼文、张华强、肖毅、何志强、陈国权和吴宗书,2017,《隐性补贴、要素市场扭曲与货币政策》,《海南金融》第2期,第4~19页。
[15] 杨振兵和张诚,2015,《中国工业部门产能过剩的测度与影响因素分析》,《南开经济研究》第6期,第92~109页。
[16] 杨小海、刘红忠和王弟海,2017,《中国应加速推进资本账户开放吗?——基于DSGE的政策模拟研究》,《经济研究》第8期,第49~64页。
[17] 周逢民,2004,《论货币政策的结构调整职能》,《金融研究》第7期,第51~56页。
[18] 中国人民银行营业管理部课题组,2017,《预算软约束、融资溢价与杠杆率——供给侧结构性改革的微观机理与经济效应研究》,《经济研究》第10期,第53~66页。
[19] 张斌、何晓贝和邓欢,2018,《不一样的杠杆:从国际比较看杠杆上升的现象、原因与影响》,《金融研究》第2期,第15~29页。
[20] 中国社会科学院国家资产负债表研究中心,2018,《中国去杠杆进程报告(2017)》。
[21] 中国人民银行金融稳定分析小组,2018,《中国金融稳定报告2018》,中国金融出版社。
[22] 中国人民大学中国宏观经济分析与预测课题组,2018,《结构性去杠杆下的中国宏观经济——2018年中期中国宏观经济分析与预测》,《经济理论与经济管理》第8期,第5~19页。
[23] Abel. A., and J. Eberly, 1999. “Investment and q with Fixed Costs: An Empirical Analysis”, working paper, Wharton school,University of Pennsylvania.
[24] Bernanke B. S., and M. Gertler., 1995. “Inside the Black Box:The Credit Channel of Monetary Policy Transmission”, The Journal of Economic Perspectives,9(4): 27~48.
[25] Calvo G. A., 1983. “Staggered Prices In a Utility-Maximizing Framework”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 12: 383~398.
[26] Cecchetti, S.G., M. S. Mohanty, and F. Zampolli., 2011. “The Real Effects of Debt”, Working Paper, BIS.
[27] Elekdag, S. and Y. Wu., 2011. “Rapid Credit Growth: Boon or Boom~Bust?” Working Paper, IMF.
[28] Fagnart, J. F., O. Licandro,and F. Portier., 1999. “Firm Heterogeneity, Capacity Utilization, and the Business Cycle”, Review of Economic Dynamics,2(2):433-455.
[29] International Monetary Fund. 2015. “Vulnerabilities, Legacies, and Policy Challenges Risks Rotating to Emerging Markets,” Global Financial Stability Report, IMF.
[30] Mendoza, E. and M. Terrones., 2008. “An Anatomy of Credit Booms: Evidence from Macro Aggregates and Micro Data”, Working Paper,NBER.
[31] Schularick, M. and A. M. Taylor., 2012. “Credit Booms Gone Bust: Monetary Policy, Leverage Cycles, and Financial Crises, 1870~2008”, American Economic Review, 102(2):1029~1061.
[1] 王弟海, 崔小勇, 邹恒甫. OLG模型中的多重均衡和经济效率——兼论政府在经济中的作用[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 443(5): 1-17.
[2] 袁东, 何秋谷, 赵波. 实际有效汇率、“热钱”流动与房屋价格——理论与实证[J]. 金融研究, 2015, 423(9): 17-33.
[1] 王曦, 朱立挺, 王凯立. 我国货币政策是否关注资产价格?——基于马尔科夫区制转换BEKK多元GARCH模型[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 1 -17 .
[2] 刘勇政, 李岩. 中国的高速铁路建设与城市经济增长[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 18 -33 .
[3] 况伟大, 王琪琳. 房价波动、房贷规模与银行资本充足率[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 34 -48 .
[4] 祝树金, 赵玉龙. 资源错配与企业的出口行为——基于中国工业企业数据的经验研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 49 -64 .
[5] 陈德球, 陈运森, 董志勇. 政策不确定性、市场竞争与资本配置[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 65 -80 .
[6] 牟敦果, 王沛英. 中国能源价格内生性研究及货币政策选择分析[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 81 -95 .
[7] 高铭, 江嘉骏, 陈佳, 刘玉珍. 谁说女子不如儿郎?——P2P投资行为与过度自信[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 96 -111 .
[8] 吕若思, 刘青, 黄灿, 胡海燕, 卢进勇. 外资在华并购是否改善目标企业经营绩效?——基于企业层面的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 112 -127 .
[9] 姜军, 申丹琳, 江轩宇, 伊志宏. 债权人保护与企业创新[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 128 -142 .
[10] 刘莎莎, 孔高文. 信息搜寻、个人投资者交易与股价联动异象——基于股票送转的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 143 -157 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1