Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2019, Vol. 474 Issue (12): 92-105    
  “货币政策与宏观审慎政策双支柱调控框架”专辑 本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
经济结构转型与“双支柱”调控框架
张斌, 熊婉婷
中国社会科学院世界经济与政治研究所,北京 100732;
中国金融四十人论坛,北京 100032
Economic Transition and the Two-Pillar Framework
ZHANG Bin, XIONG Wanting
Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences
下载:  PDF (1134KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 理解经济运行环境的变化才能更有针对性地制定和实施货币政策和宏观审慎政策。中国经济在2012年前后迈过工业化的高峰期,家庭部门发生从制造到服务的消费升级,企业部门出现从资本密集型向人力资本密集型的产业结构转型,中国的经济结构转型进程与高收入国家类似发展阶段的经历高度一致。经济结构转型过程中,传统资本密集型行业信贷需求大幅下降,新兴人力资本密集型行业信贷需求相对较低且在债务主导的金融服务体系中面临融资供给制约。由于市场内生的企业信贷供给和需求双双下降,总需求不足问题凸显。宏观经济稳定方面,宏观经济运行特征由此前的“易热难冷” 转向“易冷难热”,“债务—通缩”风险加大。这要求货币政策在执行中更加注重温和通胀目标,充分运用各种政策工具确保总需求和总供给的平衡。金融稳定方面,防范系统性风险的重点要与时俱进地调整。时间轴上要特别关注经济周期和金融周期下行叠加带来的系统性风险;空间轴上不仅要关注“大而不能倒”的系统重要性机构,还须加强“小广散”金融机构的稳定性,注重与其相关的风险传染。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
张斌
熊婉婷
关键词:  货币政策  宏观审慎  双支柱调控  经济结构转型    
Summary:  The implementation and coordination of monetary policy and macro prudential policy require an awareness of changes in the underlying macroeconomic environment.Since 2012, China has been in the process of structual transition, from a manufacturing economy to a service economy, with rising shares of human capital intensive industries (HCIIs).
   Structural transitions in the real economy impact the stability of the macro economy and the financial market. Recently, the major risk to macroeconomic stability has shifted from overheating to overcooling. To stabilize macroeconomic performance, the growth in aggregate demand should be consistent with the growth in aggregate supply. The inconsistency in this relationship is indicated by the inflation rate. During the 2002-2012 period, the general price index, the GDP deflator, was as high as 4.7%, suggesting that the economy was overheating, showing the signs of aggregate demand outgrowing aggregate supply. Growth in aggregate demand is driven by growth in nominal purchasing power, which is caused by credit expansion. Credit expansion is mainly supported by the expansion of firms in capital-intensive industries. After 2012, the economic conditions changed. The average GDP deflator in the 2012-2018 period dropped by 3% to 1.8%. The price index for producers, PPI, witnessed a continuous drop for 18 quarters. There were two reasons for this phenomenon. First, there was a decrease in market-driven demand for credit by firms because HCIIs require less investment than capital intensive industries. Second, banks reduced the credit supply to startup firms in HCIIs due to their lack of collateral and credit records.
   As for the financial stability, the post-crisis reflections on systemic risks mainly focused on the issues of overheating and excessive risk taking, which sets the background for systemic risk has become the pressure of overcooling and insufficient risk preference. However, China is now experiencing a structural transition characterized by weak external demand. Therefore, the sources of systemic risk are now overcooling and insufficient risk taking. In the temporal dimension , new systemic risks stem from the downside pressure of both economic and financial cycles and their mutual reinforcement. In the spatial dimension, the source of contagion riskno longer “too big to fall” systemically important banks, but small financial institutions with big impacts and diversified business models. Since the implementation of the Macro-Prudential Assessment (MPA) framework in 2016, big banks that are identified as systemically important institutions have significantly improved the robustness of their balance sheets, but small and medium institutions, including urban commercial banks, rural commercial banks, and private banks, are facing larger risks.
   Given these issues, we use the “double pillar” regulation framework to make three key suggestions for managing the macro-economy and financial systems in a period of economic transition. First, monetary policy should not try to achieve too many goals; instead, it should prioritize the stabilization of aggregate demand and the achievement of moderate inflation. The major challenge for achieving these goals is the insufficient credit demand by firms and credit supply by traditional banks as a result of transitions in industrial structures. In the long term, the solution to this problem is to implement structural reforms of the financial system that give a bigger role to equity financing tools, as they provide better financial service to HCIIs and satisfy their market-driven financing needs. In the short term, more policy measures should be adopted, such as more flexible adjustment of the policy rate, lifting of loan restrictions in certain industries,and the coordinated implimentation of fiscal policy.
   Second, policy makers should consider the new systemic risks in their design of the MPA, and make improvements to related policy tools and supporting systems. To tackle the systemic risks related to troubled institutions that are small, offer diversified services, and have extensive potential impacts, we suggest three improvements to the current regulatory framework. First, to restrict high cost and high risk financial services, more of the currently unregulated financial innovations should be included in the regulatory framework. Second, there should be a stress test that considers the possibility of the simultaneous market exit of large numbers of small and medium institutions. Third, there is a need to establish a series of firewalls to prevent the contagion and aggravation of risks arising from the exit of troubled institutions.
   Third, the coordination of monetary policy and prudential regulations should take into consideration the current structure of China's financial system and make an effort to reduce the imbalance between the demand of the real sector and the supply of financial services. At the same time, adopting a moderately loose monetary policy could provide a buffer against the constraining effect of more stringent prudential regulations on credit supply, thus reducing the risk of the simultaneous bankruptcy of multiple problematic financial institutions and mutually enhancing the financial and economic cycles.
Keywords:  Monetary Policy    Macroprudential    Double-Pillar Regulation    Economic Transition
JEL分类号:  E61   E58   G28  
通讯作者:  张斌,经济学博士,研究员,中国社会科学院世界经济与政治研究所、中国金融四十人论坛,E-mail:zbiwep@126.com.   
作者简介:  熊婉婷,理学博士,助理研究员,中国社会科学院世界经济与政治研究所,E-mail:wanting_xiong@sina.com.
引用本文:    
张斌, 熊婉婷. 经济结构转型与“双支柱”调控框架[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 92-105.
ZHANG Bin, XIONG Wanting. Economic Transition and the Two-Pillar Framework. Journal of Financial Research, 2019, 474(12): 92-105.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2019/V474/I12/92
[1] 陈雨露,2019,《四十年来中央银行的研究进展及中国的实践》,《金融研究》第2期,第1~19页。
[2] 马勇,2013,《宏观审慎的动态方法论基础》,《金融评论》第3期,第25~42页。
[3] 马勇和陈雨露,2013,《宏观审慎政策的协调与搭配:基于中国的模拟分析》,《金融研究》第8期,第 61~73页。
[4] 马勇、张靖岚和陈雨露,2017,《金融周期与货币政策》,《金融研究》第3期,第37~57页。
[5] (美)瑞·达利欧《债务危机:我的应对原则》,中信出版集团,2019年3月。
[6] 王爱俭和王璟怡,2014,《宏观审慎政策效应及其与货币政策关系研究》,《经济研究》第4期,第17~31页。
[7] 张斌,2015,《从制造到服务:经验、理论与中国问题》,《比较》第5期。
[8] 张斌和邹静娴,2018,《中国经济结构转型的进展与差距》,《国际经济评论》第6期,第9~24页。
[9] 张斌、何晓贝和邓欢,2018,《不一样的杠杆——从国际比较看杠杆上升的现象、原因与影响》,《金融研究》第2期,第15~29页。
[10] 中国人民银行,2018,《中国金融稳定报告2018》,中国金融出版社。
[11] 周莉萍,2018,《货币政策与宏观审慎政策研究:共识、分歧与展望》,《经济学动态》第10期,第102~117页。
[12] 周小川,2011,《金融政策对金融危机的响应——宏观审慎政策框架的形成背景、内在逻辑和主要内容》,《金融研究》第1期,第1~14页。
[13] Akinci, O. and Olmstead-Rumsey, J. 2018. “How effective are macroprudential policies? An empirical investigation”,Journal of Financial Intermediation, 2018 (33),pp. 33~57.
[14] Angelini, P., Neri, S. and Panetta, F. 2011. “Monetary and Macroprudential Policies”, Temi di discussione.
[15] Bernanke, B. 1983. “Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression”,The American Economic Review,73(3),pp. 257~276.
[16] BIS. 2018. “Moving forward with macroprudential frameworks”, BIS Annual Economic Report, https://www.bis.orgpublarpdf/ar2018e4.htm.
[17] Boar, C., Gambacorta, L., Lombardo, G., and Pereira, S. L. 2017. “What are the Effects of Macroprudential Policies on Macroeconomic Performance? ”,BIS Quarterly Review.
[18] Buera, F.J. and Kaboski J.P. 2012. “The Rise of the Service Economy” ,American Economic Review, 102(6), pp. 2540~69.
[19] Cerutti, E., Claessens, S., and Laeven,L. 2017. “The Use and Effectiveness of Macroprudential Policies: New Evidence”,Journal of Financial Stability, 28, pp. 203~224.
[20] Claessens, S. 2016. “Regulation And Structural Change In Financial Systems”,ECB Forum on Central Banking.
[21] Dunstan, A. 2014. “The Interaction Between Monetary and Macro-prudential Policy”,Reserve Bank Bulletin, 77, Reserve Bank of New Zealand, No.11.
[22] Eggertsson, G. B. and Krugman P. 2012. “Debt,Deleveraging,and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo Approach”,The Quarterly Journal of Economics,127(3), pp.1469~1513
[23] Filardo, A. and Rungcharoenkitkul, P. 2016. “A Quantitative Vase for Leaning against the Wind”. BIS Working Papers, No.594.
[24] Fisher, I. 1933. “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions”,Econometrica, 1(4), pp.337~357.
[25] Galati, G. and Moessner, R. 2018. “What Do We Know About the Effects of Macroprudential Policy? ”, Economica, 85(340): 735~770.
[26] Koo, R. 2001. “The Japanese Economy in Balance Sheet Recession: The Real Culprit is Fallacy of Composition, not Complacency”,Business Economics, 36(2), pp.15~23.
[27] Sato, T.2014. “Macroprudential Policy and Initiatives by the Bank of Japan”, Speech at Japan Society in London, http://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/press/koen_2014datako141112b1.pdf.
[28] Svensson, L.E.O. 2018. “Monetary Policy and Macroprudential Policy: Different and Separate? ”,Canadian Journal of Economics,51(3), pp. 802~827.
[29] Ubide, A. 2015. “Interaction Between Monetary Policy and Macroprudential Policies: Challenges faced by the ECB”,Peterson Institute for International Economics.
[1] 张礼卿, 钟茜. 全球金融周期、美国货币政策与“三元悖论”[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 15-33.
[2] 谭小芬, 李源, 苟琴. 美国货币政策推升了新兴市场国家非金融企业杠杆率吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 470(8): 38-57.
[3] 贾盾, 孙溪, 郭瑞. 货币政策公告、政策不确定性及股票市场的预公告溢价效应——来自中国市场的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 469(7): 76-95.
[4] 姜富伟, 郭鹏, 郭豫媚. 美联储货币政策对我国资产价格的影响[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 467(5): 37-55.
[5] 林东杰, 崔小勇, 龚六堂. 货币政策、消费品和投资品通货膨胀——基于金融加速器视角[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 465(3): 18-36.
[6] 陈雨露. 四十年来中央银行的研究进展及中国的实践[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 464(2): 1-19.
[7] 王永钦, 徐鸿恂. 杠杆率如何影响资产价格?——来自中国债券市场自然实验的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 464(2): 20-39.
[8] 黄益平, 曹裕静, 陶坤玉, 余昌华. 货币政策与宏观审慎政策共同支持宏观经济稳定[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 70-91.
[9] 方意, 王晏如, 黄丽灵, 和文佳. 宏观审慎与货币政策双支柱框架研究——基于系统性风险视角[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 106-124.
[10] 芦东, 周梓楠, 周行. 开放经济下的“双支柱”调控稳定效应研究[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 125-146.
[11] 马骏, 何晓贝. 货币政策与宏观审慎政策的协调[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 58-69.
[12] 李斌, 吴恒宇. 对货币政策和宏观审慎政策双支柱调控框架内在逻辑的思考[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 1-17.
[13] 马勇. “双支柱”调控框架的理论与经验基础[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 18-37.
[14] 王信, 贾彦东. 货币政策和宏观审慎政策的关联及启示——基于英格兰银行的经验[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 38-57.
[15] 司登奎, 葛新宇, 曾涛, 李小林. 房价波动、金融稳定与最优宏观审慎政策[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 473(11): 38-56.
[1] 王曦, 朱立挺, 王凯立. 我国货币政策是否关注资产价格?——基于马尔科夫区制转换BEKK多元GARCH模型[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 1 -17 .
[2] 刘勇政, 李岩. 中国的高速铁路建设与城市经济增长[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 18 -33 .
[3] 况伟大, 王琪琳. 房价波动、房贷规模与银行资本充足率[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 34 -48 .
[4] 祝树金, 赵玉龙. 资源错配与企业的出口行为——基于中国工业企业数据的经验研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 49 -64 .
[5] 陈德球, 陈运森, 董志勇. 政策不确定性、市场竞争与资本配置[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 65 -80 .
[6] 牟敦果, 王沛英. 中国能源价格内生性研究及货币政策选择分析[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 81 -95 .
[7] 高铭, 江嘉骏, 陈佳, 刘玉珍. 谁说女子不如儿郎?——P2P投资行为与过度自信[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 96 -111 .
[8] 吕若思, 刘青, 黄灿, 胡海燕, 卢进勇. 外资在华并购是否改善目标企业经营绩效?——基于企业层面的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 112 -127 .
[9] 姜军, 申丹琳, 江轩宇, 伊志宏. 债权人保护与企业创新[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 128 -142 .
[10] 刘莎莎, 孔高文. 信息搜寻、个人投资者交易与股价联动异象——基于股票送转的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 143 -157 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1