Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2019, Vol. 471 Issue (9): 94-111    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
干得好不如嫁得好?——房价变动与居民婚姻观念研究
赵文哲, 刘思嘉, 史宇鹏
中央财经大学经济学院, 北京 100081;
云南省能源投资集团有限公司,云南昆明 650228;
中央财经大学经济学院, 北京 100081
Is a Good Marriage Better than a Good Job? A Study on the Change in Housing Price and the Marriage Notion
ZHAO Wenzhe, LIU Sijia, SHI Yupeng
School of Economics, Central University of Finance and Economics;
Yunnan Provincial Energy Investment Group;
School of Economics,Central University of Finance and Economics
下载:  PDF (551KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 房价的快速上涨是近年来我国经济中的重要现象,对宏观经济增长乃至微观个人的观念与行为都产生了重大的影响,但尚未有研究系统考察房价变化对居民婚姻观念的影响。房价上涨反映了对未来预期的不确定性,这种不确定性势必会影响到人们对工作与婚姻的权衡。本文基于中国综合社会调查(CGSS)2010和2015年数据,详细考察了房价变动对人们在工作与婚姻之间权衡的影响,用人们对“干得好不如嫁得好”的看法来衡量工作与婚姻的权衡。研究结果表明,房价涨幅越高,居民对“干得好不如嫁得好”的认同感越高,且这种现象主要体现在女性群体中。异质性分析表明,女性、未婚女性、已婚女性、女性流动人口、城镇户籍女性以及拥有女儿数量越多的人在工作与婚姻的权衡中更倾向于通过婚姻来抵御未来预期不确定性产生的风险。房价上涨主要通过财富效应和预算约束效应对人们在工作与婚姻之间的权衡产生影响。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
赵文哲
刘思嘉
史宇鹏
关键词:  房价  婚姻观念  财富效应  预算约束效应    
Summary:  The rapid increase in housing prices is a popular phenomenon demonstrated by China's economy in recent years. Housing is one of the most important assets for a family, so a rapid housing price increase implies rapid change in family wealth, which has great impacts on individuals' decisions and attitudes. In traditional Chinese culture, the notion that a good marriage is better than a good job plays an important role in one's decision to marry. Some surveys show that this perspective remains popular in Chinese society. Much of the literature analyzes the effects of social circumstances and physical foundations on this notion from the view of female psychology and sociology, but few studies discuss the effects of economic factors.
For rational individuals, the trade-off decision between marriage and employment must involve the consideration of economic factors, such as the change in housing prices. Theoretically, the housing price level reflects a city's cost of living and income levels. The change in housing prices reflects expected uncertainty in the future, with higher changes in housing prices indicating greater expected uncertainty in the future. The rapid increase in housing prices implies not only the increase in nominal family wealth, but also the expected increase in housing expenditure. Therefore, the change in housing prices can affect the trade-off between marriage and employment through two channels. The first channel is the wealth effect. This channel implies that with the rapid increase in housing prices, the nominal wealth of individuals with housing increases. As the motivation to avoid the risk of future uncertainty by marriage decreases, the change in housing prices causes individuals to prefer employment to marriage. The second channel is the budgetary constraint effect. Specifically, the increase in housing prices implies a large future expenditure, which exerts great pressure on individuals with lower income and more liability. In this case, the change in housing prices causes individuals to prefer marriage to employment to avoid the risk of future uncertainty.
Based on China's General Social Survey (CGSS) data of 2010 and 2015, we examine whether people prefer a good marriage to a good job due to the increase in housing prices. We use the notion of a good job or a good marriage as the trade-off between employment and marriage. The baseline regression of the probit model shows that the higher the increase in housing prices is, the more likely people are to prefer a good marriage. This finding remains robust when we change the dependent variable and the explanatory variable of housing level (we replace the housing price-income ratio with the urban real value of housing price level). Heterogeneous analyses show that females, unmarried females, married females, female migrants, urban females, and people with more daughters prefer marriage to employment when facing increased housing prices. This preference allows them to avoid the risk of future uncertainty. Finally, we test the mechanisms of the wealth effect and the budgetary constraint effect. We test the wealth effect by dividing the sample into three groups according to the number of housing properties owned and who has the property. We find that the rapid increase in housing prices increases the nominal wealth of females with more housing such that their sense of identification with the notion that a good marriage is better than a good job is lower. We test the budgetary constraint effect by designing the regression according to individual income level. The probit regression shows that the increase in housing prices leads females with lower incomes to increase their acceptance of the notion that a good marriage is better than a good job, as they would suffer stronger budgetary constraints in the face of rapidly increasing housing prices.
Although the notion that a good marriage is better than a good job is culturally rooted, economic factors such as housing prices can also affect it. Our main contribution is our analysis of the relationship between housing price and the notion of marriage and our discussion of the probable mechanisms of the wealth effect and the budgetary constraint effect. With the rapid rate of housing price increase in recent years, more and more young females are prioritizing a good marriage. This is expected to exert greater pressure on the labor market and lead to a lower rate of female labor participation. As the increase in housing price does not significantly increase the marriage preference of males, but increases males' preference for employment at the cost of delaying marriage, it may further decrease fertility in the future. Thus, this problem is worthy of further research.
Keywords:  Housing Price    Marriage Notion    Wealth Effect    Budgetary Constraint Effect
JEL分类号:  O18   R30   Z13  
基金资助: * 本文感谢国家自然科学基金面上项目(编号:71773153)、北京市哲学社会科学规划一般项目(编号:14JGB083)、国家社科基金重大招标项目(编号:14ZDB120)和中央财经大学青年科研创新团队支持计划的资助。
作者简介:  赵文哲,经济学博士,副教授,中央财经大学经济学院,E-mail:zwenzhe@163.com.
刘思嘉,经济学硕士,云南省能源投资集团有限公司,E-mail:15368393201@126.com.
史宇鹏(通讯作者):经济学博士,教授,中央财经大学经济学院、中央财经大学全球经济与可持续发展研究中心,E-mail:shiyupeng@cufe.edu.cn.
引用本文:    
赵文哲, 刘思嘉, 史宇鹏. 干得好不如嫁得好?——房价变动与居民婚姻观念研究[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 471(9): 94-111.
ZHAO Wenzhe, LIU Sijia, SHI Yupeng. Is a Good Marriage Better than a Good Job? A Study on the Change in Housing Price and the Marriage Notion. Journal of Financial Research, 2019, 471(9): 94-111.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2019/V471/I9/94
[1] 蔡栋梁、何翠香和方行明,2015,《住房及房价预期对家庭创业的影响》,《财经科学》第6期,第108~118页。
[2] 陈斌开和杨汝岱,2013,《土地供给、住房价格与中国城镇居民储蓄》,《经济研究》第1期,第111~122页。
[3] 陈彥斌和邱哲圣,2011,《高房价如何影响居民储蓄率和财产不平等》,《经济研究》第10期,第25~38页。
[4] 陈永伟、顾佳峰和史宇鹏,2014,《住房财富、信贷约束与城镇家庭教育开支——来自CFPS2010数据的证据》,《经济研究》增第1期,第89~101页。
[5] 范子英和胡贤敏,2015,《未预期的收入冲击与离婚:来自住房市场的证据》,《华中科技大学学报》第1期,第111~117。
[6] 傅鑫媛、文佳佳和寇彧,2014,《大城市职场未婚女性的安全感对其择偶中物质倾向的影响》,《心理科学》第4期,第950~956页。
[7] 洪彩妮,2012,《房价波动影响结婚决策的研究》,《当代青年研究》第2期,第17~23页。
[8] 黄静和图梅曾,2009,《房地产财富与消费:来自于家庭微观调查数据的证据》,《管理世界》第7 期,第35~45页。
[9] 林江、周少君和魏万青,2012,《城市房价、住房产权与主观幸福感》,《财贸经济》第5期,第114~120页。
[10] 刘军岭,2017,《房价、住房产权条件与城镇居民社会信任》,《现代财经》(天津财经大学学报)第2期,第26-38页。
[11] 彭代彦和闵秋红,2015,《住房消费与国民幸福——基于CGSS2013年的实证分析》,《广西社会科学》第12期,第85~90页。
[12] 钱铭怡、王易平、章晓云和朱松,2003,《十五年来中国女性择偶标准的变化》,《北京大学学报》(哲学社会科学版)第5期,第121~128页。
[13] 田芊,2012,《中国女性择偶倾向研究》,复旦大学博士学位论文。
[14] 万江红和闵莎,2014,《观念的变迁与现实的制约:干得好不如嫁得好——基于第三期湖北省妇女社会地位调查数据的分析》,《中南民族大学学报》(人文社会科学版)第11期,第97~102页。
[15] 王弟海、管文杰和赵占波,2015,《土地和住房供给对房价变动和经济增长的影响》,《金融研究》第1期,第50~67页。
[16] 吴伟平、章元和刘乃全,2016,《房价与女性劳动参与决策》,《经济学动态》第11期,第57~67页。
[17] 吴晓瑜、王敏和李力行,2014,《中国的高房价是否阻碍了创业?》,《经济研究》第9期,第121~134页。
[18] 许琪,2016,《中国人性别观念的变化趋势、来源和异质性——以“男主外、女主内”和“干得好不如嫁得好”两个指标为例》,《妇女研究论丛》,第3期,第33~43页。
[19] 易君健和易行键,2008《房价上涨与生育率的长期下降:基于香港的实证分析》,《经济学(季刊)》第7卷第3期,第961~982页。
[20] 於嘉和谢宇,2013,《社会变迁与初婚影响因素的变化》,《社会学研究》第4期,第1~25页。
[21] 张莉、何晶和马润泓等,2017,《房价如何影响劳动力流动?》,《经济研究》第8期,第155~170页。
[22] 张巍、许家云和杨竺松,2018,《房价、工资与资源配置效率——基于微观家庭数据的实证分析》第8期,第69~84页。
[23] 赵文哲、边彩云和董丽霞,2018,《城镇化、城市房价与农村流动人口户籍迁移》,《财经问题研究》第6期,第122~130页。
[24] 赵西亮、梁文泉和李实,2013,《房价上涨能够解释中国城镇居民高储蓄率吗?——基于CHIP微观数据的实证分析》,《经济学(季刊)》第13卷第1期,第81~102页。
[25] 祝继高、李天时和尤可畅,2017,《房地产价格波动与商业银行贷款损失准备——基于中国城市商业银行的实证研究》,《金融研究》第9期,第83~98页。
[26] Becker, Gary S, 1973. “A Theory of Marriage: Part I”,Journal of Political Economy,81(4): 813~846.
[27] Becker, Gary S.,Elisabeth M. Landes and Robert T. Michae,1977. ”An Economic Analysis of Marital Instability”, Journal of Political Economy,85(6), pp.1141~1187.
[28] Detling, Lisa J. and Kearney, Melissa Schettini, 2014. “House Prices and Birth Rates: The Impact of the Real Estate Market on the Decision to Have a Baby”, Journal of Public Economics, 110: 82~100.
[29] Disney, Richard and Gathergood, John, 2014. “House Prices Wealth Effect and Labor Supply”, IFS Working Paper W14/25.
[30] Fu Shihe,Liao, Yu and Zhang, Junfu, 2016. “The Effect of Housing Wealth on Labor Force Participation: Evidence from China”, Journal of Housing Economics, 33: 59~69.
[31] Han, Libin and Lu, Ming, 2017. “Housing Prices and Investment: an Assessment of China's Inland-favoring Land Supply Policies”, Journal of The Asia Pacific Economy, 22(1): 106~121.
[32] Li, Lixing, and Wu, Xiaoyu, 2014. “Housing Prices and Enterpreneurship in China”, Journal of Comparative Economics, 42: 436~449.
[33] Wang, Shing-Yi, 2012. “Credit Constraint, Job Mobility and Entrepreneurship: Evidence from a Property Reform in China”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 94: 532~551.
[34] Wang, Xin and Wen, Yi, 2012. “Housing Prices and the High Chinese Saving Rate Puzzle”, China Economic Review, 23: 265~283.
[35] Wei, Shangjin and Zhang, Xiaobo, 2011. “The Competitive Saving Motive: Evidence from Rising Sex Ratios and Savings Rates in China”, Journal of Political Economy, 3, pp511~564.
[36] Yi, Junjian and Zhang, Junsen, 2010. “The Effect of Housing Price on Fertility: Evidence from Hong Kong”, Economic Inquiry, 48(3): 635~650.
[1] 周广肃, 王雅琦. 住房价格、房屋购买与中国家庭杠杆率[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 468(6): 1-19.
[2] 司登奎, 葛新宇, 曾涛, 李小林. 房价波动、金融稳定与最优宏观审慎政策[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 473(11): 38-56.
[3] 张巍, 许家云, 杨竺松. 房价、工资与资源配置效率——基于微观家庭数据的实证分析[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 458(8): 69-84.
[4] 庞家任, 周桦, 王玮. 上市公司成立并购基金的影响因素及财富效应研究[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 452(2): 153-171.
[5] 吴雨, 李洁, 尹志超. 房价上涨对P2P网络借贷成本的影响分析——来自“人人贷”的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 461(11): 85-97.
[6] 张浩, 易行健, 周聪. 房产价值变动、城镇居民消费与财富效应异质性——来自微观家庭调查数据的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 446(8): 50-66.
[7] 魏玮, 陈杰. 加杠杆是否一定会成为房价上涨的助推器?——来自省际面板门槛模型的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 450(12): 48-63.
[8] 况伟大, 王琪琳. 房价波动、房贷规模与银行资本充足率[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 34-48.
[9] 龙少波, 陈璋, 胡国良. 货币政策、房价波动对居民消费影响的路径研究[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 432(6): 52-66.
[10] 刘行, 建蕾, 梁娟. 房价波动、抵押资产价值与企业风险承担[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 429(3): 107-123.
[11] 袁东, 何秋谷, 赵波. 实际有效汇率、“热钱”流动与房屋价格——理论与实证[J]. 金融研究, 2015, 423(9): 17-33.
[12] 邹瑾, 于焘华, 王大波. 人口老龄化与房价的区域差异研究——基于面板协整模型的实证分析[J]. 金融研究, 2015, 425(11): 64-79.
[13] 张浩, 李仲飞, 邓柏峻. 政策不确定、宏观冲击与房价波动——基于LSTVAR模型的实证分析[J]. 金融研究, 2015, 424(10): 32-47.
[1] 王曦, 朱立挺, 王凯立. 我国货币政策是否关注资产价格?——基于马尔科夫区制转换BEKK多元GARCH模型[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 1 -17 .
[2] 刘勇政, 李岩. 中国的高速铁路建设与城市经济增长[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 18 -33 .
[3] 况伟大, 王琪琳. 房价波动、房贷规模与银行资本充足率[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 34 -48 .
[4] 祝树金, 赵玉龙. 资源错配与企业的出口行为——基于中国工业企业数据的经验研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 49 -64 .
[5] 陈德球, 陈运森, 董志勇. 政策不确定性、市场竞争与资本配置[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 65 -80 .
[6] 牟敦果, 王沛英. 中国能源价格内生性研究及货币政策选择分析[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 81 -95 .
[7] 高铭, 江嘉骏, 陈佳, 刘玉珍. 谁说女子不如儿郎?——P2P投资行为与过度自信[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 96 -111 .
[8] 吕若思, 刘青, 黄灿, 胡海燕, 卢进勇. 外资在华并购是否改善目标企业经营绩效?——基于企业层面的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 112 -127 .
[9] 姜军, 申丹琳, 江轩宇, 伊志宏. 债权人保护与企业创新[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 128 -142 .
[10] 刘莎莎, 孔高文. 信息搜寻、个人投资者交易与股价联动异象——基于股票送转的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 143 -157 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1