Summary:
Since the reform and opening-up policy, China's economy has made remarkable achievements with innovation playing an important role. As China enters a phase of high-quality development, innovation is becoming increasingly important. However, innovation is characterized by a high failure rate and high risk, causing enterprise decision makers' risk tolerance to be the basic determinant of corporate innovation. The ownership structure of listed companies in China is highly concentrated, and the ultimate controller determines the company's major decisions. Although ultimate controllers' wealth concentration has an impact on enterprise innovation through risk tolerance, few studies focus on this issue. Taking Chinese private listed companies as an example, this paper examines whether ultimate controllers' wealth concentration affects corporate innovation. In theory, high wealth concentration of ultimate controllers may have both positive and negative effects. The risk diversification hypothesis suggests that higher wealth concentration will increase the actual controllers' risk exposure level, reduce their risk preference, and lead to a lower tolerance for innovation failure, thus inhibiting corporate innovation. However, the information hypothesis suggests that higher wealth concentration makes the actual controller more capable and energetic to obtain and analyze the enterprise's internal and external information, to make better innovation decisions and activities, and to ultimately contribute to corporate innovation. Based on manually collected data on actual controllers' wealth concentration, this paper empirically studies the influence of the wealth concentration of actual controllers in private listed companies on corporate innovation. The results show that the higher the ultimate controllers' wealth concentration, the lower the level of innovation. The mechanism test shows that ultimate controllers' wealth concentration reduces enterprises' risk-taking. These results support the risk diversification hypothesis, which states that the higher the ultimate controllers' wealth concentration, the lower their tolerance for innovation failure will be, hindering corporate innovation. Further research shows that government subsidies can act as a risk buffer and reduce the negative effect of ultimate controllers' wealth concentration on innovation by dispersing innovation risks. Institutional investors can play a monitoring and balancing role to reduce the negative impact of ultimate controllers' wealth concentration on innovation by restraining risk aversion. Finally, when ultimate controllers' wealth concentration is higher, the controllers are more likely to engage in technology takeovers to compensate for insufficient independent innovation. Our paper makes several contributions to the literature. First, taking Chinese private listed companies with highly concentrated equity as an example, this paper studies the influence of actual controllers' wealth concentration on innovation and thus contributes to the literature on corporate innovation. Second, this paper supplements studies on the relationship between government subsidies and corporate innovation from the perspective of government subsidies acting as a risk buffer. Third, from the perspective of limiting ultimate controllers' risk aversion, this paper expands the literature on institutional investors' governance role. Fourth, from the substitution effect of technology mergers and acquisitions (M&A) on independent innovation, this paper expands research on technology M&A. To stimulate private enterprises' innovation, this paper has the following policy implications. First, the individual income tax rate for the restricted transfer of shares in listed companies should be lowered to reduce the cost of actual controllers' wealth dispersion, encourage wealth dispersion, and thus stimulate the innovation of private enterprises. Second, the differentiated arrangement of voting rights should be expanded and strengthened to reduce the risk of loss of control rights caused by diversifying actual controllers' ownership rights, encourage actual controllers to diversify their wealth investment, and stimulate private enterprises' innovation. Third, the government should play a risk-sharing role in corporate innovation to improve ultimate controllers' innovation failure tolerance and stimulate private enterprises' innovation. Finally, we should develop institutional investors and increase their voting power surrounding corporate innovation so that they can better play a monitoring and balancing role against the self-interest of actual controllers with concentrated wealth, which will further stimulate private enterprises' innovation.
潘红波, 杨朝雅, 李丹玉. 如何激发民营企业创新——来自实际控制人财富集中度的视角[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 502(4): 114-132.
PAN Hongbo, YANG Zhaoya, LI Danyu. How to Stimulate Private Enterprises' Innovation: Evidence from Ultimate Controllers' Wealth Concentration. Journal of Financial Research, 2022, 502(4): 114-132.
[1]陈德萍和陈永圣,2011,《股权集中度、股权制衡度与公司绩效关系研究——2007~2009年中小企业板块的实证检验》,《会计研究》第1期,第38~43页。 [2]姜付秀、郑晓佳和蔡文婧,2017,《控股家族的“垂帘听政”与公司财务决策》,《管理世界》第3期,第125~145页。 [3]姜军、江轩宇和伊志宏,2020,《企业创新效率研究——来自股权质押的影响》,《金融研究》第2期,第128~146页。 [4]孔东民、刘莎莎、陈小林和邢精平,2015,《个体沟通、交易行为与信息优势:基于共同基金访问的证据》,《经济研究》第11期,第106~119页。 [5]李万福、杜静和张怀,2017,《创新补助究竟有没有激励企业创新自主投资——来自中国上市公司的新证据》,《金融研究》第10期,第130~145页。 [6]毛其淋和许家云,2015,《政府补贴对企业新产品创新的影响——基于补贴强度“适度区间”的视角》,《中国工业经济》第6期,第94~107页。 [7]石美娟和童卫华,2009,《机构投资者提升公司价值吗?——来自后股改时期的经验证据》,《金融研究》第10期,第150~161页。 [8]史永东和王谨乐,2014,《中国机构投资者真的稳定市场了吗?》,《经济研究》第12期,第100~112页。 [9]唐跃军和左晶晶,2014,《所有权性质、大股东治理与公司创新》,《金融研究》第6期,第177~192页。 [10]王艳,2016,《混合所有制并购与创新驱动发展——广东省地方国企“瀚蓝环境”2001~2015年纵向案例研究》,《管理世界》第8期,第150~163页。 [11]王彦超和蒋亚含,2020,《竞争政策与企业投资——基于〈反垄断法〉实施的准自然实验》,《经济研究》第8期,第137~152页。 [12]解维敏、唐清泉和陆姗姗,2009,《政府R&D资助,企业R&D支出与自主创新——来自中国上市公司的经验证据》,《金融研究》第6期,第86~99页。 [13]杨海燕、韦德洪和孙健,2012,《机构投资者持股能提高上市公司会计信息质量吗?——兼论不同类型机构投资者的差异》,《会计研究》第9期,第16~23页。 [14]杨瑞龙、章逸然和杨继东,2017,《制度能缓解社会冲突对企业风险承担的冲击吗?》,《经济研究》第8期,第140~154页。 [15]余明桂、钟慧洁和范蕊,2016,《业绩考核制度可以促进央企创新吗?》,《经济研究》第12期,第104~117页。 [16]赵世芳、江旭、应千伟和霍达,2020,《股权激励能抑制高管的急功近利倾向吗——基于企业创新的视角》,《南开管理评论》第6期,第76~87页。 [17]赵子夜、杨庆和陈坚波,2018,《通才还是专才:CEO的能力结构和公司创新》,《管理世界》第2期,第123~143页。 [18]朱冰、张晓亮和郑晓佳,2018,《多个大股东与企业创新》,《管理世界》第7期,第151~165页。 [19]Ahuja, G. and R. Katila. 2001. “Technological Acquisitions and the Innovation Performance of Acquiring Firms: A Longitudinal Study”, Strategic Management Journal, 22(3): 197~220. [20]Aminadav, G. and E. Papaioannou. 2020. “Corporate Control around the World”, The Journal of Finance, 75(3): 1191~1246. [21]Baranchuk, N. , R. Kieschnick and R. Moussawi. 2014. “Motivating Innovation in Newly Public Firms”, Journal of Financial Economics, 111(3): 578~588. [22]Bernstein, S. 2015. “Does Going Public Affect Innovation?”, The Journal of Finance, 70(4): 1365~1403. [23]Bushee, B. J. 1998. “The Influence of Institutional Investors on Myopic R&D Investment Behavior”, The Accounting Review, 73(3): 305~333. [24]Edmans, A. 2009. “Blockholder Trading, Market Efficiency, and Managerial Myopia”, The Journal of Finance, 64(6): 2481~2513. [25]Faccio, M. , M. Marchica and R. Mura. 2011. “Large Shareholder Diversification and Corporate Risk-Taking”, The Review of Financial Studies, 24(11): 3601~3641. [26]Grinblatt, M. and M. Keloharju. 2001. “How Distance, Language, and Culture Influence Stockholdings and Trades”, The Journal of Finance, 56(3): 1053~1073. [27]He, J. , X. Mao , O. M. Rui and X. Zha. 2013. “Business Groups in China”, Journal of Corporate Finance, 22: 166~192. [28]He, J. J. and X. Tian. 2013. “The Dark Side of Analyst Coverage: The Case of Innovation”, Journal of Financial Economics, 109(3): 856~878. [29]Hirshleifer, D. , A. Low and S. H. Teoh. 2012. “Are Overconfident CEOs Better Innovators?”, The Journal of Finance, 67(4): 1457~1498. [30]Howell, S. T. 2017. “Financing Innovation: Evidence from R&D Grants”, American Economic Review, 107(4): 1136~1164. [31]Lyandres, E. , M. Marchica , R. Michaely and R. Mura. 2019. “Owners' Portfolio Diversification and Firm Investment”, The Review of Financial Studies, 32(12): 4855~4904. [32]Mamuneas, T. P. and M. I. Nadiri. 1996. “Public R&D Policies and Cost Behavior of the US Manufacturing Industries”, Journal of Public Economics, 63(1): 57~81. [33]Manso, G. 2011. “Motivating Innovation”, The Journal of Finance, 66(5): 1823~1860. [34]Markowitz, H. 1952. “Portfolio Selection”, The Journal of Finance,,7(1): 77~91. [35]Ni, X. and S. Yin. 2018. “Shareholder Litigation Rights and the Cost of Debt: Evidence from Derivative Lawsuits”, Journal of Corporate Finance, 48: 169~186. [36]Shleifer, A. and R. W. Vishny. 1990. “Equilibrium Short Horizons of Investors and Firms”, The American Economic Review, 80(2): 148~153. [37]Tian, X. and T. Y. Wang. 2014. “Tolerance for Failure and Corporate Innovation”, The Review of Financial Studies, 27(1): 211~255. [38]Wulf, J. 2002. “Internal Capital Markets and Firm-Level Compensation Incentives for Division Managers”, Journal of Labor Economics, 20(S2): S219~S262. [39]Zhong, R. I. 2018. “Transparency and Firm Innovation”, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 66(1): 67~93.