Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2020, Vol. 486 Issue (12): 56-74    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
加征关税如何影响美国贸易逆差及全球福利——基于美元本位下两国动态一般均衡框架的分析
刘凯
中国人民大学经济学院/中国经济改革与发展研究院,北京 100872
How Increasing Tariffs Affects the U.S. Trade Deficit and Global Welfare: An Analysis Based on a Two-Country Dynamic General Equilibrium Framework Incorporating the Dollar Standard
LIU Kai
School of Economics/Institute of China's Economic Reform & Development, Renmin University of China
下载:  PDF (1487KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 本文构建了一个包含美元本位特征的两国模型,在此基础上分析了美国加征关税及引发的贸易摩擦对美国贸易逆差和全球福利的影响,并详细探讨了相关传导机制。在基准模型设定下,美国单方面加征20%关税会使得美国贸易逆差占GDP比重小幅缩小约0.40个百分点,美国长期稳态GDP下降约2.50%,其他国家GDP下降约1.10%,美国居民福利上升约0.60%,其他国家居民福利下降约1.20%。美国单方面加征关税在抑制全球贸易和生产的同时,会通过更加不公平的国际贸易恶化全球福利分配。当其他国家采取报复性措施时,其他国家自身福利并不会进一步恶化,但美国福利会大幅下滑,同时美国贸易逆差相对规模变化不大。贸易摩擦博弈的“囚徒困境”特征在一定程度上能够解释贸易战的发生。削弱美元本位地位能促进国际贸易公平性的提升,进而能减弱贸易摩擦带来的负面影响、提升全球福利水平,并能有效缩窄美国贸易逆差。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
刘凯
关键词:  关税  贸易逆差  美元本位  贸易战  囚徒困境    
Summary:  During recent years protectionism has come to dominate U.S. trade policy. The U.S. has tried to narrow its long-standing large trade deficit and to protect its industries by imposing tariffs on other countries, refusing to support multilateral trading systems, and by other means. Relevant data show that since the collapse of the Bretton Woods system and the establishment of the Jamaican system in the 1970s, the global economic imbalances that are exemplified by the U.S. trade deficit have continued for more than 40 years. Although these imbalances have shown some volatility, in essence they are a set of long-term phenomena. In addition, the U.S. has maintained a long-term trade deficit with almost all of its main trading partners, not just China, and thus the U.S. trade deficit is also a structural phenomenon. In fact, the dollar-standard characteristic of the current international monetary system is one of the root causes of the long-term U.S. trade deficit. The questions explored in this paper are as follows. If the important role of the dollar standard in determining the persistent U.S. trade deficit is taken into account, can the U.S. tariffs draw down the size of the U.S. trade deficit, and how do these tariffs affect the welfare of global residents? What would happen if other economies retaliated against the U.S.? In the face of a U.S.-sponsored trade war, could weakening the dollar standard boost the welfare of other economies? To answer these questions, this paper constructs a two-country dynamic general equilibrium model that incorporates the characteristics of the dollar standard. Based on this model, the paper analyzes the impacts of U.S. tariffs and the trade war on both the U.S. trade deficit and on global welfare, while discussing the relevant transmission mechanism in detail. Under the benchmark model setting, if the U.S. unilaterally imposes an extra 20% tariff, it will reduce the U.S. trade deficit-GDP ratio by about 0.40 percentage points. In addition, the U.S. long-term steady-state GDP will fall by about 2.50%, while the overall GDP of other countries will fall by about 1.10%. U.S. welfare will rise by about 0.60%, and the welfare of other countries will fall by about 1.20%. The unilateral increase in tariffs imposed by the U.S. will curb global trade and production, and worsen the distribution of global welfare through unfair terms of international trade. When other countries take retaliatory measures, that is, when the trade war breaks out, the welfare of other countries will not deteriorate further, but U.S. welfare will fall sharply, and the relative scale of the U.S. trade deficit will not change much. The “prisoner's dilemma” feature of the trade war game can, to a certain extent, explain the occurrence of the trade war. Weakening the dollar standard can help to promote fairness in international trade, which can weaken the negative impacts of the trade war, raise the level of global welfare, and effectively narrow the U.S. trade deficit. This paper offers two main contributions to the existing literature. First, it analyzes the long-term effects that the U.S. tariffs and trade war have on the U.S. trade deficit and on global economic imbalances. This analysis involves constructing a quantitative macroeconomic general equilibrium model, which has been lacking in the existing literature. Second, this paper discusses the impacts of the U.S. tariff and trade war with full consideration for the factor of the dollar standard, which is one important factor that has been neglected in the existing literature. Therefore, this paper's analysis is better aligned with the reality of the world economy than previous studies.
Keywords:  Tariff    Trade Deficit    Dollar Standard    Trade War    Prisoner's Dilemma
JEL分类号:  E42   F13   F41   F55  
基金资助: * 本文受北京高校“双一流”建设资金支持,并受到国家自然科学基金青年项目“美元本位下中国金融开放与最优货币政策研究”(项目号71503253)以及“中国工业经济学会青年杯最佳论文奖”资助。特别感谢陈彦斌教授、杨春学教授、李钢研究员、陈国进教授、陈斌开教授、杨诶教授以及中国人民大学经济学院、上海财经大学金融学院、中国青年经济学家联谊会工作坊(北京·2018)、厦门大学经济学院、中国工业经济学会青年杯等研讨会参与者以及匿名审稿人的有益建议,感谢王度州的助研工作,文责自负。
作者简介:  刘 凯,经济学博士,副教授,中国人民大学经济学院、中国经济改革与发展研究院,E-mail:liukeynes@ruc.edu.cn.
引用本文:    
刘凯. 加征关税如何影响美国贸易逆差及全球福利——基于美元本位下两国动态一般均衡框架的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 486(12): 56-74.
LIU Kai. How Increasing Tariffs Affects the U.S. Trade Deficit and Global Welfare: An Analysis Based on a Two-Country Dynamic General Equilibrium Framework Incorporating the Dollar Standard. Journal of Financial Research, 2020, 486(12): 56-74.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2020/V486/I12/56
[1] 陈勇兵、陈小鸿、曹亮和李兵,2014,《中国进口需求弹性的估算》,《世界经济》第2期,第28~49页。
[2] 段玉婉、刘丹阳和倪红福,2018,《全球价值链视角下的关税有效保护率——兼评美国加征关税的影响》,《中国工业经济》第7期,第62~79页。
[3] 樊海潮和张丽娜,2018,《中间品贸易与中美贸易摩擦的福利效应:基于理论与量化分析的研究》, 《中国工业经济》第9期,第41~59页。
[4] 李晓和周学智,2012,《美国对外负债的可持续性:外部调整理论的扩展》, 《世界经济》第12期, 第130~155页。
[5] 刘凯,2017,《美元本位、全球经济失衡与人民币国际化》,《人文杂志》第5期,第54~64页。
[6] 刘凯,2018,《中国特色的土地制度如何影响中国经济增长——基于多部门动态一般均衡框架的分析》,《中国工业经济》第10期,第 80~98页。
[7] 沈琪和周世民,2014,《进口关税减免与企业全要素生产率: 来自中国的微观证据》,《管理世界》第9期, 第174~175页。
[8] 盛斌和毛其淋,2017,《进口贸易自由化是否影响了中国制造业出口技术复杂度》,《世界经济》第12期,第52~75页。
[9] 田巍和余淼杰,2014,《中间品贸易自由化和企业研发: 基于中国数据的经验分析》,《世界经济》第6期,第90~112页。
[10] 仝冰,2017,《混频数据、投资冲击与中国宏观经济波动》,《经济研究》第6期,第60~76页。
[11] 佟苍松和熊晓琳,2007,《美国对进口中国制造业商品执行的关税政策》,《世界经济》第11期,第24~31页。
[12] 王道平和范小云,2011,《现行的国际货币体系是否是全球经济失衡和金融危机的原因》,《世界经济》第1期,第52~72页。
[13] 余淼杰和袁东,2016,《贸易自由化, 加工贸易与成本加成——来自我国制造业企业的证据》,《管理世界》第9期,第33~43页。
[14] 张顺明和余军,2009,《内部货币与我国最优关税政策研究》,《经济研究》第2期,第18~31页。
[15] Alessandria, G. and H. Choi. 2014. “Establishment Heterogeneity, Exporter Dynamics, and the Effects of Trade Liberalization”, Journal of International Economics, 94(2): 207~223.
[16] Alves, N., S. Gomes, and J. Sousa. 2007. “An Open Economy Model of the Euro Area and the US”, Banco de Portugal, Economics and Research Department Working Papers, No. W200718.3.4.
[17] Bagwell, K. and R.W. Staiger. 1999. “An Economic Theory of GATT”, American Economic Review, 89(1): 215~248.
[18] Bagwell, K. and R.W. Staiger. 2011. “What Do Trade Negotiators Negotiate About? Empirical Evidence from the World Trade Organization”, American Economic Review, 101(4): 1238~1273.
[19] Caliendo, L., R.C. Feenstra, J. Romalis, and A.M. Taylor. 2015. “Tariff Reductions, Entry, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for the Last Two Decades”, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Papers, No. w21768.
[20] Caliendo, L. and F. Parro. 2015. “Estimates of the Trade and Welfare Effects of NAFTA”, Review of Economic Studies, 82(1): 1~44.
[21] Chen, Y., K. Liu, and Z. Liu. 2018. “U.S. Money Supply and China's Business Cycles”, Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 54(5): 957~980.
[22] Chu, A.C., G. Cozzi, C. Lai, and C. Liao. 2015. “Inflation, R&D and Growth in an Open Economy”, Journal of International Economics, 96, 360~374.
[23] Funke, M., M. Paetz, and E. Pytlarczyk. 2010. “Stock Market Wealth Effects in an Estimated DSGE Model for Hong Kong”, Economic Modelling, 28: 316~334.
[24] Gali, J. and T. Monacelli. 2005. “Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy”, Review of Economic Studies, 72(3): 707~734.
[25] Ganelli, G. and J. Tervala. 2015. “Value of WTO Trade Agreements in a New Keynesian Model”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 45(37): 347~362.
[26] Handley, K. and N. Limão. 2017. “Policy Uncertainty, Trade, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for China and the United States”, American Economic Review, 107(9): 2731~2783.
[27] Nisticó, S. 2012. “Monetary Policy and Stock-price Dynamics in a DSGE Framework”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 34: 126~146.
[28] Ossa, R. 2011. “A ‘New Trade' Theory of GATT/WTO Negotiations”, Journal of Political Economy, 119(1): 122~152.
[1] 陈元. 信用与资本——开发性金融研究[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 478(4): 1-10.
[2] 纪敏, 李宏瑾. 影子银行、资管业务与货币调控方式转型——基于银行表外理财数据的实证分析[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 462(12): 1-18.
[3] 徐忠, 邹传伟. 区块链能做什么、不能做什么?[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 461(11): 1-16.
[4] 温信祥, 苏乃芳. 大资管、影子银行与货币政策传导[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 460(10): 38-54.
[5] 姚前. 共识规则下的货币演化逻辑与法定数字货币的人工智能发行[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 459(9): 37-55.
[6] 战明华, 李欢. 金融市场化进程是否改变了中国货币政策不同传导渠道的相对效应?[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 455(5): 20-36.
[7] 牛慕鸿, 张黎娜, 张翔. 利率走廊、利率稳定性和调控成本[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 445(7): 16-28.
[8] 姚前, 汤莹玮. 关于央行法定数字货币的若干思考[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 445(7): 78-85.
[9] 马理, 何梦泽, 刘艺. 基于适应性预期的货币政策传导研究[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 434(8): 19-33.
[10] 余琰, 李怡宗. 高息委托贷款与企业创新[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 430(4): 99-114.
[1] 王曦, 朱立挺, 王凯立. 我国货币政策是否关注资产价格?——基于马尔科夫区制转换BEKK多元GARCH模型[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 1 -17 .
[2] 刘勇政, 李岩. 中国的高速铁路建设与城市经济增长[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 18 -33 .
[3] 况伟大, 王琪琳. 房价波动、房贷规模与银行资本充足率[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 34 -48 .
[4] 祝树金, 赵玉龙. 资源错配与企业的出口行为——基于中国工业企业数据的经验研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 49 -64 .
[5] 陈德球, 陈运森, 董志勇. 政策不确定性、市场竞争与资本配置[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 65 -80 .
[6] 牟敦果, 王沛英. 中国能源价格内生性研究及货币政策选择分析[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 81 -95 .
[7] 李丹, 庞晓波, 方红生. 财政空间与中国政府债务可持续性[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 448(10): 1 -17 .
[8] 项后军, 闫玉. 理财产品发展、利率市场化与银行风险承担问题研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 448(10): 99 -114 .
[9] 李万福, 杜静, 张怀. 创新补助究竟有没有激励企业创新自主投资——来自中国上市公司的新证据[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 448(10): 130 -145 .
[10] 潘越, 肖金利, 戴亦一. 文化多样性与企业创新:基于方言视角的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 448(10): 146 -161 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1