Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2020, Vol. 476 Issue (2): 15-33    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
全球金融周期、美国货币政策与“三元悖论”
张礼卿, 钟茜
中央财经大学金融学院, 北京 100081
The Global Financial Cycle, US Monetary Policy, and the Impossible Trinity
ZHANG Liqing, ZHONG Qian
School of Finance, Central University of Finance and Economics
下载:  PDF (1501KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 全球金融周期存在的背景下“三元悖论”是否依然成立充满争议。本文通过构建包含银行与金融摩擦的两国DSGE模型,为考察全球金融周期的形成提供了理论依据。美国货币政策通过资本流动传导到外围国金融市场,使外围国信贷利率、银行风险承担以及杠杆率与美国银行趋同,形成全球金融周期。金融渠道的传导速度快于实体经济渠道导致外围国国内经济周期与金融周期相背离,外围国想要稳定经济就不得不与美国保持同向的政策利率变化,货币政策独立性将不再存在。随着全球经济一体化进程加速,估值效应的作用越来越明显,浮动汇率制度并不能隔离全球金融周期的影响也无法保证货币政策的独立性。在资本账户开放的情况下,外围国金融市场越不发达,受全球金融周期的影响越大,货币政策越不独立。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
张礼卿
钟茜
关键词:  全球金融周期  三元悖论  资本流动  货币政策溢出效应  DSGE    
Summary:  The notion of the Impossible Trinity holds that one country can only fulfill two of the following three conditions: a fixed exchange rate system, the free flow of capital, and independence of monetary policy. However, due to the continuous development of financial globalization, more and more studies have found that US monetary policy can influence peripheral countries' economies through the flow of capital, bank balance sheet, foreign exchange reserves and other channels because of other countries' preference for the dollar. A flexible exchange rate does not ensure the independence of monetary policy. Rey (2013) found increasing global synchronization among capital flows, asset prices, financial leverage, and credit growth.
   Rgy(2013) defines this synchronization as the “Global Financial Cycle,” which is negatively related to VIX. The Global Financial Cycle has been widely discussed. Many studies acknowledge its existence, and use VIX as the proxy variable to study the relationship between the Global Financial Cycle and the independence of monetary policy. The research methods of these studies are SVAR or panel regression; few discuss the theoretical causes of the Global Financial Cycle. Therefore, this paper constructs a two-country DSGE model including bank and financial frictions to theoretically analyze the causes of the Global Financial Cycle and discuss whether the monetary policies of peripheral countries with flexible exchange rates are independent.
   A partial equilibrium analysis based on the theoretical derivation finds that the policy interest rate affects the balance sheets and decision-making behavior of banks. As a result, the equity asset ratio, market interest rate, and bank survival rate change with the policy interest rate. Therefore, the cause of the Global Financial Cycle is the synchronization of the policy interest rates of various countries. Through impulse response analysis, it is found that even countries with flexible exchange rates need to change their monetary policy rate in the same direction as the Federal Funds Rate to maintain domestic financial and economic stability.
   Counterfactual simulation of flexible exchange rate countries with different degrees of capital liberalization shows that the spillover effect of US monetary policy through the Business Cycle is opposite of the spillover effect through the Global Financial Cycle. The impact and transmission speed of the Global Financial Cycle is far greater than that of the Business Cycle. Take the loose monetary policy of the United States as an example. The rapid availability of domestic credit in peripheral countries leads to overinvestment, overcapacity, and oversupply of commodities. The economy shifts from the real to the fictitious, and the real economy declines because of poor return on investment. The real economy is asynchronous with the financial cycle. To deal with this asynchrony, peripheral countries must also loosen monetary policy to restrain capital inflow. The synchronization of monetary policies in different countries leads to the synchronization of financial markets, which is to say the Global Financial Cycle.
   Further research finds that as international investment increases, the impact of the valuation effect is so large that the exchange rate cannot completely offset the central country's spillover effect. The valuation effect is one reason why a flexible exchange rate country without capital control has no monetary policy independence. The depth of the financial market and the independence of monetary policy are complementary. US monetary policy spillover has a greater impact on countries with less developed financial markets.
   The conclusions of this study lead to the following suggestions. First, it is necessary to strengthen macro prudential supervision to restrain the excessive risk-taking behavior of financial institutions. Second, moderate capital control is workable, especially when the global financial market is in a boom period.
JEL分类号:  E58   F2   G2  
通讯作者:  钟茜,博士研究生,中央财经大学金融学院,E-mail:18146558362@163.com.    
作者简介:  张礼卿,经济学博士,教授,中央财经大学金融学院、国际金融研究中心,E-mail:zhlq@cufe.edu.cn.
引用本文:    
张礼卿, 钟茜. 全球金融周期、美国货币政策与“三元悖论”[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 15-33.
ZHANG Liqing, ZHONG Qian. The Global Financial Cycle, US Monetary Policy, and the Impossible Trinity. Journal of Financial Research, 2020, 476(2): 15-33.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2020/V476/I2/15
[1] 邓创和徐曼,2014,《中国的金融周期波动及其宏观经济效应的时变特征研究》,《数量经济技术经济研究》第9期,第75~91页。
[2] 江曙霞和陈玉婵,2012,《货币政策、银行资本与风险承担》,《金融研究》第4期,第1~16页。
[3] 金雪军、黄滕和祝宇,2013,《中国商品市场名义价格粘性的测度》,《经济研究》第9期,第85~98页。
[4] 陆简,2017,《避险情绪、货币乘数与二元悖论》,《国际金融研究》第6期,第3~12页。
[5] 郑振龙和汤文玉,2011,《波动率风险及风险价格——来自中国A股市场的证据》,《金融研究》第4期,第143~157页。
[6] Aizenman, J., M. Chinn, and H. Ito. 2016. “Monetary Policy Spillovers and the Trilemma in the New Normal: Periphery Country Sensitivity to Core Country Conditions”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 68 (3):298~330.
[7] Bernanke, B., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1996. “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(1):1~15.
[8] Bocola, L. 2016. “The Pass-through of Sovereign Risk”, Journal of Political Economy, 124(4):879~926.
[9] Bruno, V., and H. S. Shin. 2015. “Cross Border Banking and Global Liquidity”, Review of Economic Studies, 82(2):535~564.
[10] Calvo, G. A., L. Leiderman, and C. Reinhart. 1996. “Capital Flows to Developing Countries in the 1990s: Causes and Effects”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(1):123~139.
[11] Cerutti, E., S. Claessens, and A. K. Rose. 2017. “How Important is the Global Financial Cycle? Evidence from Capital Flows”, NBER Working Paper No. 23699.
[12] Chinn, M. D., and S. J. Wei. 2013. “A Faith-Based Initiative Meets the Evidence: Does a Flexible Exchange Rate Regime Really Facilitate Current Account Adjustment?” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 95(1):168~184.
[13] Coimbra, N., and Hélène Rey. 2017. “Financial Cycles with Heterogeneous Intermediaries”, NBER Working Paper No.23245.
[14] Dell’Ariccia, G., L. Laeven, and R. Marquez. 2014. “Real Interest Rates, Leverage, and Bank Risk-Taking”, Journal of Economic Theory, 149(1):65~99.
[15] Dooley, M., D. Folkerts-Landau, and P. Garber. 2009. “Bretton Woods II Still Defines the International Monetary System”, Pacific Economic Review, 14 (3):297~311.
[16] Edwards, S. 2015. “Monetary Policy Independence under Flexible Exchange Rates: An Illusion?” World Economy, 38(5):773~787.
[17] Eichengreen, B., A. Mehl, and Livia Chitu. 2017. “How Global Currencies Work: Past, Present, and Future,” Princeton University Press.
[18] Fostel, A., J. Geanakoplos, and G. Phelan. 2019. “Global Collateral and Capital Flows”, NBER Working Paper No. 25583.
[19] Gebka, B., and D. Serwa. 2007. “Intra-and Inter-regional Spillovers between Emerging Capital Market Around the World”, International Business and Finance, 21(2):203~221.
[20] Georgiadis, G., and Feng Zhu. 2019. “Monetary Policy Spillovers, Capital Controls and Exchange Rate Flexibility, and the Financial Channel of Exchange Rates”, European Central Bank Working Paper No. 2267.
[21] Ghosh, A. R., M. S. Qureshi, J. Kim, and J. Zalduendo. 2014. “Surges”, Journal of International Economics, 92 (2):266~285.
[22] Han, X., and Shang-Jin Wei. 2014. “Policy Choices and Resilience to International Monetary Shocks”, Global Economic Review, 43 (4):319~337.
[23] Han, X., and Shang-Jin Wei. 2018. “International Transmissions of Monetary Shocks: Between a Trilemma and a Dilemma”, Journal of International Economics, 110(1):205~219.
[24] Kharroubi, E., and F. Zampolli. 2016. “Monetary Independence in a Financially IntegratedWorld: What Do Measures of Interest Rate Co-movement Tell Us?” BIS Working Papers No.88.
[25] Klein, M. W., and J. C. Shambaugh. 2015. “Rounding the Corners of the Policy Trilemma: Sources of Monetary Policy Autonomy”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 7 (4):33~66.
[26] Lane, P. R., and J. C. Shambaugh. 2010. “Financial Exchange Rates and International Currency Exposures”, American Economic Review, 100 (1):518~540.
[27] Miyakoshi, Tatsuyoshi. 2013. “Spillovers of Stock Return Volatility to Asian Equity Market from Japan and the US”, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 13(4):383~399.
[28] Nier, E., T. S. Sedik, and T. Mondino. 2014. “Gross Private Capital Flows to Emerging Markets: Can the Global Financial Cycle Be Tamed?” IMF Working Paper No. 14/196.
[29] Obstfeld, M. 2015. “Trilemmas and Tradeoffs: Living with Financial Globalization”, BIS Working Papers No. 480.
[30] Passari, E., and H. Rey. 2015. “Financial Flows and the International Monetary System”, Economic Journal, 125 (5):675~698.
[31] Rappoport, V. 2009. “Persistence of Dollarization After Price Stabilization”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 56 (7):979~989.
[32] Rey, H. 2013. “Dilemma Not Trilemma: The Global Financial Cycle and Monetary Policy Independence”, NBER Working Paper No. 21162.
[33] Schularick, M., and A. M. Taylor. 2012. “Credit Booms Gone Bust: Monetary Policy, Leverage Cycles, and Financial Crises, 1870-2008”, American Economic Review, 102 (2):1029~1061.
[34] Tong, H., and S. J. Wei. 2011. “The Composition Matters: Capital Inflows and Liquidity Crunch During a Global Economic Crisis”, Review of Financial Studies, 24(6):2023~2052.
[1] 徐忠, 贾彦东. 中国潜在产出的综合测算及其政策含义[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 465(3): 1-17.
[2] 林东杰, 崔小勇, 龚六堂. 货币政策、消费品和投资品通货膨胀——基于金融加速器视角[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 465(3): 18-36.
[3] 王遥, 潘冬阳, 彭俞超, 梁希. 基于DSGE模型的绿色信贷激励政策研究[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 473(11): 1-18.
[4] 陈思翀, 刘静雅. 套息交易对中国短期资本流动的影响——基于动态资产组合理论的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 456(6): 73-90.
[5] 汪勇, 马新彬, 周俊仰. 货币政策与异质性企业杠杆率——基于纵向产业结构的视角[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 455(5): 47-64.
[6] 李晓峰, 陈雨蒙. 基于变系数模型的我国资本流动审慎管理研究[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 454(4): 20-34.
[7] 童中文, 范从来, 张炜, 朱辰. 金融审慎监管与货币政策的协同效应——虑及金融系统性风险防范[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 441(3): 16-32.
[8] 李力, 王博, 刘潇潇, 郝大鹏. 短期资本、货币政策和金融稳定[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 435(9): 18-32.
[9] 丁志杰, 田园. 论资本项目有管理可兑换[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 428(2): 96-105.
[10] 马鑫媛, 赵天奕. 非正规金融与正规金融双重结构下货币政策工具比较研究[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 428(2): 137-144.
[11] 伍戈, 陆简. 全球避险情绪与资本流动——“二元悖论”成因探析[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 437(11): 1-14.
[12] 项后军, 何 康, 于 洋. 自贸区设立、贸易发展与资本流动——基于上海自贸区的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 436(10): 48-63.
[13] 马骏, 施康, 王红林, 王立升. 利率传导机制的动态研究[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 427(1): 31-49.
[1] 周小川. 养老金改革考验我们经济学的功底和智慧[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 475(1): 1 -8 .
[2] 邹文理, 王曦, 谢小平. 中央银行沟通的金融市场响应──基于股票市场的事件研究[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 34 -50 .
[3] 卢冰, 王雅琦, 洪圣杰. 人民币预期汇率变动与虚假贸易——基于套汇视角的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 475(1): 9 -27 .
[4] 陈雨露. 当前全球中央银行研究的若干重点问题[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 1 -14 .
[5] 戴静, 杨筝, 刘贯春, 许传华. 银行业竞争、创新资源配置和企业创新产出——基于中国工业企业的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 51 -70 .
[6] 戴魁早, 刘友金. 市场化改革能推进产业技术进步吗?——中国高技术产业的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 71 -90 .
[7] 程新生, 武琼, 刘孟晖, 程昱. 企业集团现金分布、管理层激励与资本配置效率[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 91 -108 .
[8] 顾雷雷, 郭建鸾, 王鸿宇. 企业社会责任、融资约束与企业金融化[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 109 -127 .
[9] 姜军, 江轩宇, 伊志宏. 企业创新效率研究——来自股权质押的影响[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 128 -146 .
[10] 武佳薇, 汪昌云, 陈紫琳, Jie Michael Guo. 中国个人投资者处置效应研究——一个非理性信念的视角[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 476(2): 147 -166 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1