Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2025, Vol. 535 Issue (1): 1-19    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
庞氏融资、去杠杆与宏观审慎政策
马勇, 章洪铭
中国人民大学财政金融学院/中国财政金融政策研究中心,北京 100872
Ponzi Financing, Deleveraging and Macroprudential Policy
MA Yong, ZHANG Hongming
School of Finance/China Financial Policy Research Center, Renmin University of China, School of Finance, Renmin University of China
下载:  PDF (1467KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 企业高负债与金融不稳定可能制约经济高质量发展,如何为经济转型升级提供更为稳定和富有弹性的宏观环境,以较小代价推动企业摆脱债务依赖,是亟待思考的议题。本文基于明斯基理论,构造包含“庞氏融资”特征的DSGE模型,分析去杠杆政策、宏观审慎政策以及二者组合使用的稳定效应。相关结果表明:(1)结构性去杠杆政策可以起到良好的稳定作用,但在降低庞氏企业融资扩张能力的过程中,需要与合适的宏观审慎政策配合才能实现经济金融体系的整体稳定;(2)在宏观审慎政策支持下,结构性去杠杆政策存在一个相对较优的实施方案,即首先将庞氏企业的债务率降至合理水平,然后控制其融资扩张能力,最后促进企业回归实体经济;(3)在去杠杆不同阶段,政策当局的政策空间存在差异:在降杠杆阶段,政策调整需要慎重地综合权衡,避免经济大幅波动;在控杠杆阶段,宏观审慎政策的运用可以更加灵活,政策空间也相应增加;而在“脱虚向实”阶段,政策空间将被充分释放,政策实施的灵活性大幅提高。本文为理解去杠杆过程中的经济金融互动和相关政策选择提供了一些新的思考和证据。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
马勇
章洪铭
关键词:  庞氏融资  去杠杆  宏观审慎政策  DSGE模型    
Summary:  The global macroeconomic leverage ratios have witnessed a sustained upward trend in recent years, drawing renewed international attention to high debt levels and financial instability. According to BIS statistics, from March 2009 to December 2023, the non-financial corporate leverage ratio across G20 nations increased from 79.0% to 91.7%, while China's ratio surged more markedly from 99.4% to 134.7% during the same period. Particularly noteworthy is that China's non-financial corporate leverage ratio once approached 150% around 2015. As China's economy transitions into the “New Normal”, shifting development focus from rapid growth to quality enhancement has become imperative for sustaining healthy economic development. However, persistent corporate debt accumulation and financial system instability have significantly hindered this economic transformation. This context raises a crucial practical question: how to achieve effective deleveraging with minimal economic disruption while ensuring domestic financial stability, thereby establishing a robust foundation for industrial restructuring and upgrading. This is an urgent policy challenge demanding thorough exploration and innovative solutions.
Particularly under the current conditions where China's economy is facing “Triple Pressure” and “Three Periods Overlapping”, the profitability of the corporate sector is under stress. This has led some enterprises to increasingly rely on debt to maintain their cash flow balance and business operations, thus exhibiting the characteristics of firm type transformation revealed in Minsky's theory. Discussing the endogenous combination of deleveraging policies and macro policies based on Minsky's theory is also a significant theoretical issue that requires ongoing and in-depth study. In light of this, this paper constructs a DSGE model with “Ponzi Financing”, introducing heterogeneous entrepreneurial sectors with different financing characteristics and a financial sector with a “dual structure”. This model is used to systematically analyze the stabilizing effects under the application of deleveraging policies, macro-prudential policies, and their combined use.
The analysis results of this paper indicate that: (1) Structural deleveraging policies can play a good stabilizing role, but in the process of reducing the financing expansion capabilities of Ponzi enterprises, they need to be combined with appropriate macroprudential policies to achieve overall stability of the economy and financial system. (2) With the support of macroprudential policies, there is a relatively optimal implementation scheme for structural deleveraging policies, which involves first reducing the debt ratio of Ponzi enterprises to a reasonable level, then controlling their financing expansion capabilities, and finally promoting a return to the real economy. (3) The policy authority has different policy spaces at different stages of deleveraging: During the leverage reduction stage, policy adjustments need to be carefully balanced to avoid causing significant economic fluctuations; In the leverage control stage, the use of macro-prudential policies can be more flexible, and the policy space correspondingly increases; In the stage of shifting from “financial to real”, the policy space will be fully released, and the flexibility of policy implementation will be greatly enhanced.
The policy implications of the conclusions of this paper are: Although the main sources of economic and financial instability are the excessive indebtedness and investment by entrepreneurs and bankers chasing profits, and a reduction in investment is a crucial trigger for the “Minsky Moment”, this does not imply that loosening financing constraints can avoid potential economic and financial risks. On the contrary, arbitrarily easing financing constraints may lead to significant resource misallocation, thereby exacerbating the vulnerability of the economic and financial system. Therefore, loosening financing constraints is not a viable solution to the “Minsky Moment”. Theoretically, if we view the “Minsky Moment” as a deleveraging process accompanied by significant negative impacts, then policymakers should adopt differentiated strategies for high-debt entities, aiming to complete the deleveraging process with minimal negative impact. From the perspective of Minsky's theory, deleveraging should include at least two aspects: reducing the debt level of Ponzi financing enterprises and controlling their financing expansion capability. If policies can separately regulate the debt level and financing expansion capability of micro-agents, rather than simply prohibiting or reducing lending outright, the relevant market entities may be able to choose a more reasonable path to complete the deleveraging process at a relatively lower cost.
Keywords:  Ponzi Financing    Deleveraging    Macroprudential Policy    DSGE Model
JEL分类号:  E44   E58   G18  
基金资助: * 本文感谢国家社会科学基金重大项目(21ZDA044)的资助。感谢匿名审稿人的宝贵意见,文责自负。
通讯作者:  章洪铭,博士研究生,中国人民大学财政金融学院,E-mail:zhanghongming@ruc.edu.cn.   
作者简介:  马 勇,经济学博士,教授,中国人民大学财政金融学院/中国财政金融政策研究中心,E-mail:mayongmail@ruc.edu.cn.
引用本文:    
马勇, 章洪铭. 庞氏融资、去杠杆与宏观审慎政策[J]. 金融研究, 2025, 535(1): 1-19.
MA Yong, ZHANG Hongming. Ponzi Financing, Deleveraging and Macroprudential Policy. Journal of Financial Research, 2025, 535(1): 1-19.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2025/V535/I1/1
[1]陈彦斌、刘哲希和陈伟泽,2018,《经济增速放缓下的资产泡沫研究——基于含有高债务特征的动态一般均衡模型》,《经济研究》第10期,第16~32页。
[2]戴华娟、陈乐一和王超,2021,《双重金融摩擦与宏观审慎政策的经济稳定效应——基于动态随机一般均衡模型的分析》,《国际金融研究》第9期,第14~24页。
[3]郝大鹏、王博和李力,2020,《美联储政策变化、国际资本流动与宏观经济波动》,《金融研究》第7期,第38~56页。
[4]侯成琪和刘颖,2015,《外部融资溢价机制与抵押约束机制——基于DSGE模型的比较研究》,《经济评论》第4期,第134~147页。
[5]侯成琪和黄彤彤,2020,《影子银行、监管套利和宏观审慎政策》,《经济研究》第7期,第58~75页。
[6]李力、温来成、唐遥和张偲,2020,《货币政策与宏观审慎政策双支柱调控下的地方政府债务风险治理》,《经济研究》第11期,第36~49页。
[7]刘哲希和李子昂,2018,《结构性去杠杆进程中居民部门可以加杠杆吗》,《中国工业经济》第10期,第42~60页。
[8]马勇,2013,《植入金融因素的DSGE模型与宏观审慎货币政策规则》,《世界经济》第7期,第68~92页。
[9]马勇和陈雨露,2017,《金融杠杆、杠杆波动与经济增长》,《经济研究》第6期,第31~45页。
[10]马勇和付莉,2020,《“双支柱”调控、政策协调搭配与宏观稳定效应》,《金融研究》第 8期,第1~17页。
[11]马勇和吕琳,2021,《“双支柱”政策、政府债务与财政政策效果》,《经济研究》第11期,第30~47页。
[12]马勇和章洪铭,2024,《中国DSGE建模中的参数估计》,《金融评论》第6期,第27~68页。
[13]孟宪春和张屹山,2021,《家庭债务、房地产价格渠道与中国经济波动》,《经济研究》第5期,第75~90页。
[14]孙国峰和何晓贝,2017,《存款利率零下限与负利率传导机制》,《经济研究》第12期,第105~118页。
[15]谭语嫣、谭之博、黄益平和胡永泰,2017,《僵尸企业的投资挤出效应:基于中国工业企业的证据》,《经济研究》第5期,第175~188页。
[16]吴世农、陈韫妍、吴育辉和汪金祥,2021,《企业融资模式、金融市场安全性及其变动特征》,《中国工业经济》第8期,第37~55页。
[17]谢德仁和史学智,2023,《地区汇总的庞氏利息程度变化与商业银行不良贷款预测》,《金融研究》第8期,第55~73页。
[18]谢富胜和匡晓璐,2020,《制造业企业扩大金融活动能够提升利润率吗?——以中国A股上市制造业企业为例》,《管理世界》第12期,第13~28页。
[19]叶莉、王苗和许文立,2021,《政府债务高杠杆、金融稳定与“双支柱”调控框架》,《投资研究》第11期,第4~18页。
[20]诸竹君、黄先海和王煌,2019,《僵尸企业如何影响企业加成率——来自中国工业企业的证据》,《财贸经济》第6期,第131~146页。
[21]Benigno, P., G. B. Eggertsson and F. Romei, 2020, “Dynamic Debt Deleveraging and Optimal Monetary Policy”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 12(2), pp.310~350.
[22]Eggertsson, G. B. and P. Krugman, 2012, “Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo Approach”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(3), pp.1469~1513.
[23]Fazzari, S., P. Ferri and E. Greenberg, 2008, “Cash flow, Investment, and Keynes-Minsky Cycles”, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 65(3-4), pp.555~572.
[24]Foley, D. K., 1987, “Liquidity-profit Rate Cycles in a Capitalist Economy”, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 8(3), pp.363~376.
[25]Gerali, A., S. Neri, L. Sessa and M. Signoretti, 2010, “Credit and Banking in a DSGE Model of the Euro Area”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42(6), pp.107~141.
[26]Iacoviello, M., 2005, “House Prices, Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle”, American Economic Review, 95(3), pp.739~764.
[27]Keen, S., 1995, “Finance and Economic Breakdown: Modeling Minsky's ‘Financial Instability Hypothesis’”, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 17(4), pp.607~635.
[28]Minsky, H. P., 1986,Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New Haven : Yale University Press.
[29]Taylor, L. and S. A. O'Connell, 1985, “A Minsky Crisis”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, pp.871~885.
[30]Woodford, M., 2012, “Inflation Targeting and Financial Stability”, NBER Working Paper, No.17967.
[1] 虞梦微, 谭小芬, 宋佳馨. 全球金融周期、宏观审慎政策和跨境资本流动——兼论“三元悖论”和“二元悖论”之争[J]. 金融研究, 2024, 528(6): 1-19.
[2] 徐飘洋, 王博. “双支柱”政策的结构性功能——基于产业绿色转型视角[J]. 金融研究, 2024, 524(2): 19-37.
[3] 林滨, 孙乾, 王弟海. 不确定性冲击、结构性失业与稳就业政策——基于公共—企业两部门定向搜寻匹配模型的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2024, 533(11): 1-19.
[4] 李志辉, 朱明皓, 李源, 李政. 我国金融机构的系统性风险溢出研究:测度、渠道与防范对策[J]. 金融研究, 2023, 514(4): 55-73.
[5] 吴迪, 张楚然, 侯成琪. 住房价格、金融稳定与宏观审慎政策[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 505(7): 57-75.
[6] 祝梓翔, 高然. 通胀—增长权衡和中国菲利普斯曲线的平坦化[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 509(11): 1-20.
[7] 马勇, 吕琳. 货币、财政和宏观审慎政策的协调搭配研究[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 499(1): 1-18.
[8] 钱宗鑫, 王芳, 孙挺. 金融周期对房地产价格的影响——基于SV-TVP-VAR模型的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 489(3): 58-76.
[9] 马勇, 付莉. “双支柱”调控、政策协调搭配与宏观稳定效应[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 482(8): 1-17.
[10] 黄继承, 姚驰, 姜伊晴, 牟天琦. “双支柱”调控的微观稳定效应研究[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 481(7): 1-20.
[11] 张智富, 郭云喜, 张朝洋. 宏观审慎政策协调能否抑制国际性银行危机传染?——基于跨境金融关联视角的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 481(7): 21-37.
[12] 郝大鹏, 王博, 李力. 美联储政策变化、国际资本流动与宏观经济波动[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 481(7): 38-56.
[13] 杨伟中, 余剑, 李康. 金融资源配置、技术进步与经济高质量发展[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 486(12): 75-94.
[14] 林东杰, 崔小勇, 龚六堂. 货币政策、消费品和投资品通货膨胀——基于金融加速器视角[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 465(3): 18-36.
[15] 王信, 贾彦东. 货币政策和宏观审慎政策的关联及启示——基于英格兰银行的经验[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 38-57.
[1] 张晓宇, 徐龙炳. 限售股解禁、资本运作与股价崩盘风险[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 158 -174 .
[2] 王攀娜, 罗宏. 放松卖空管制对分析师预测行为的影响——来自中国准自然实验的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 191 -206 .
[3] 祝继高, 李天时, 尤可畅. 房地产价格波动与商业银行贷款损失准备——基于中国城市商业银行的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 447(9): 83 -98 .
[4] 史永东, 王龑. 职务犯罪是否加剧了银行风险?——来自中国城商行和农商行的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 447(9): 99 -114 .
[5] 陈辉, 顾乃康. 新三板做市商制度、股票流动性与证券价值[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 442(4): 176 -190 .
[6] 罗进辉, 向元高, 金思静. 中国资本市场低价股的溢价之谜[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 439(1): 191 -206 .
[7] 李万福, 杜静, 张怀. 创新补助究竟有没有激励企业创新自主投资——来自中国上市公司的新证据[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 448(10): 130 -145 .
[8] 黄宪, 黄彤彤. 论中国的“金融超发展”[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 440(2): 26 -41 .
[9] 李政. “811汇改”提高了人民币汇率中间价的市场基准地位吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 442(4): 1 -16 .
[10] 王曦, 朱立挺, 王凯立. 我国货币政策是否关注资产价格?——基于马尔科夫区制转换BEKK多元GARCH模型[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 1 -17 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1