Summary:
The global macroeconomic leverage ratios have witnessed a sustained upward trend in recent years, drawing renewed international attention to high debt levels and financial instability. According to BIS statistics, from March 2009 to December 2023, the non-financial corporate leverage ratio across G20 nations increased from 79.0% to 91.7%, while China's ratio surged more markedly from 99.4% to 134.7% during the same period. Particularly noteworthy is that China's non-financial corporate leverage ratio once approached 150% around 2015. As China's economy transitions into the “New Normal”, shifting development focus from rapid growth to quality enhancement has become imperative for sustaining healthy economic development. However, persistent corporate debt accumulation and financial system instability have significantly hindered this economic transformation. This context raises a crucial practical question: how to achieve effective deleveraging with minimal economic disruption while ensuring domestic financial stability, thereby establishing a robust foundation for industrial restructuring and upgrading. This is an urgent policy challenge demanding thorough exploration and innovative solutions. Particularly under the current conditions where China's economy is facing “Triple Pressure” and “Three Periods Overlapping”, the profitability of the corporate sector is under stress. This has led some enterprises to increasingly rely on debt to maintain their cash flow balance and business operations, thus exhibiting the characteristics of firm type transformation revealed in Minsky's theory. Discussing the endogenous combination of deleveraging policies and macro policies based on Minsky's theory is also a significant theoretical issue that requires ongoing and in-depth study. In light of this, this paper constructs a DSGE model with “Ponzi Financing”, introducing heterogeneous entrepreneurial sectors with different financing characteristics and a financial sector with a “dual structure”. This model is used to systematically analyze the stabilizing effects under the application of deleveraging policies, macro-prudential policies, and their combined use. The analysis results of this paper indicate that: (1) Structural deleveraging policies can play a good stabilizing role, but in the process of reducing the financing expansion capabilities of Ponzi enterprises, they need to be combined with appropriate macroprudential policies to achieve overall stability of the economy and financial system. (2) With the support of macroprudential policies, there is a relatively optimal implementation scheme for structural deleveraging policies, which involves first reducing the debt ratio of Ponzi enterprises to a reasonable level, then controlling their financing expansion capabilities, and finally promoting a return to the real economy. (3) The policy authority has different policy spaces at different stages of deleveraging: During the leverage reduction stage, policy adjustments need to be carefully balanced to avoid causing significant economic fluctuations; In the leverage control stage, the use of macro-prudential policies can be more flexible, and the policy space correspondingly increases; In the stage of shifting from “financial to real”, the policy space will be fully released, and the flexibility of policy implementation will be greatly enhanced. The policy implications of the conclusions of this paper are: Although the main sources of economic and financial instability are the excessive indebtedness and investment by entrepreneurs and bankers chasing profits, and a reduction in investment is a crucial trigger for the “Minsky Moment”, this does not imply that loosening financing constraints can avoid potential economic and financial risks. On the contrary, arbitrarily easing financing constraints may lead to significant resource misallocation, thereby exacerbating the vulnerability of the economic and financial system. Therefore, loosening financing constraints is not a viable solution to the “Minsky Moment”. Theoretically, if we view the “Minsky Moment” as a deleveraging process accompanied by significant negative impacts, then policymakers should adopt differentiated strategies for high-debt entities, aiming to complete the deleveraging process with minimal negative impact. From the perspective of Minsky's theory, deleveraging should include at least two aspects: reducing the debt level of Ponzi financing enterprises and controlling their financing expansion capability. If policies can separately regulate the debt level and financing expansion capability of micro-agents, rather than simply prohibiting or reducing lending outright, the relevant market entities may be able to choose a more reasonable path to complete the deleveraging process at a relatively lower cost.
[1]陈彦斌、刘哲希和陈伟泽,2018,《经济增速放缓下的资产泡沫研究——基于含有高债务特征的动态一般均衡模型》,《经济研究》第10期,第16~32页。 [2]戴华娟、陈乐一和王超,2021,《双重金融摩擦与宏观审慎政策的经济稳定效应——基于动态随机一般均衡模型的分析》,《国际金融研究》第9期,第14~24页。 [3]郝大鹏、王博和李力,2020,《美联储政策变化、国际资本流动与宏观经济波动》,《金融研究》第7期,第38~56页。 [4]侯成琪和刘颖,2015,《外部融资溢价机制与抵押约束机制——基于DSGE模型的比较研究》,《经济评论》第4期,第134~147页。 [5]侯成琪和黄彤彤,2020,《影子银行、监管套利和宏观审慎政策》,《经济研究》第7期,第58~75页。 [6]李力、温来成、唐遥和张偲,2020,《货币政策与宏观审慎政策双支柱调控下的地方政府债务风险治理》,《经济研究》第11期,第36~49页。 [7]刘哲希和李子昂,2018,《结构性去杠杆进程中居民部门可以加杠杆吗》,《中国工业经济》第10期,第42~60页。 [8]马勇,2013,《植入金融因素的DSGE模型与宏观审慎货币政策规则》,《世界经济》第7期,第68~92页。 [9]马勇和陈雨露,2017,《金融杠杆、杠杆波动与经济增长》,《经济研究》第6期,第31~45页。 [10]马勇和付莉,2020,《“双支柱”调控、政策协调搭配与宏观稳定效应》,《金融研究》第 8期,第1~17页。 [11]马勇和吕琳,2021,《“双支柱”政策、政府债务与财政政策效果》,《经济研究》第11期,第30~47页。 [12]马勇和章洪铭,2024,《中国DSGE建模中的参数估计》,《金融评论》第6期,第27~68页。 [13]孟宪春和张屹山,2021,《家庭债务、房地产价格渠道与中国经济波动》,《经济研究》第5期,第75~90页。 [14]孙国峰和何晓贝,2017,《存款利率零下限与负利率传导机制》,《经济研究》第12期,第105~118页。 [15]谭语嫣、谭之博、黄益平和胡永泰,2017,《僵尸企业的投资挤出效应:基于中国工业企业的证据》,《经济研究》第5期,第175~188页。 [16]吴世农、陈韫妍、吴育辉和汪金祥,2021,《企业融资模式、金融市场安全性及其变动特征》,《中国工业经济》第8期,第37~55页。 [17]谢德仁和史学智,2023,《地区汇总的庞氏利息程度变化与商业银行不良贷款预测》,《金融研究》第8期,第55~73页。 [18]谢富胜和匡晓璐,2020,《制造业企业扩大金融活动能够提升利润率吗?——以中国A股上市制造业企业为例》,《管理世界》第12期,第13~28页。 [19]叶莉、王苗和许文立,2021,《政府债务高杠杆、金融稳定与“双支柱”调控框架》,《投资研究》第11期,第4~18页。 [20]诸竹君、黄先海和王煌,2019,《僵尸企业如何影响企业加成率——来自中国工业企业的证据》,《财贸经济》第6期,第131~146页。 [21]Benigno, P., G. B. Eggertsson and F. Romei, 2020, “Dynamic Debt Deleveraging and Optimal Monetary Policy”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 12(2), pp.310~350. [22]Eggertsson, G. B. and P. Krugman, 2012, “Debt, Deleveraging, and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo Approach”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(3), pp.1469~1513. [23]Fazzari, S., P. Ferri and E. Greenberg, 2008, “Cash flow, Investment, and Keynes-Minsky Cycles”, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 65(3-4), pp.555~572. [24]Foley, D. K., 1987, “Liquidity-profit Rate Cycles in a Capitalist Economy”, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 8(3), pp.363~376. [25]Gerali, A., S. Neri, L. Sessa and M. Signoretti, 2010, “Credit and Banking in a DSGE Model of the Euro Area”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42(6), pp.107~141. [26]Iacoviello, M., 2005, “House Prices, Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle”, American Economic Review, 95(3), pp.739~764. [27]Keen, S., 1995, “Finance and Economic Breakdown: Modeling Minsky's ‘Financial Instability Hypothesis’”, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 17(4), pp.607~635. [28]Minsky, H. P., 1986,Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New Haven : Yale University Press. [29]Taylor, L. and S. A. O'Connell, 1985, “A Minsky Crisis”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, pp.871~885. [30]Woodford, M., 2012, “Inflation Targeting and Financial Stability”, NBER Working Paper, No.17967.