Income Gaps, Credit Constraints, and House Price Fluctuations
CHEN Jinzhi, WEN Xingchun, SONG Lu
School of Government Audit, Nanjing Audit University; School of Banking and Finance, University of International Business and Economics; National Academy of Development and Strategy, Renmin University of China
Summary:
Income gaps, credit constraints, and housing prices are long-established and prominent topics of social concern. International Monetary Fund (IMF) figures from September 2020 report a record high global real house price index of 167.26 (using the first quarter of 2000 as the base period). The data show a rising trend in 47 of the 63 sampled countries and regions. Furthermore, since the U.S. subprime mortgage crisis, many scholars have investigated the potential relationships between income gaps and credit constraints. Numerous papers show that relaxation of credit constraints contributes significantly to rising house prices. Although this finding raises a natural question of how income gaps influence house prices through credit channels, this question is rarely mentioned in the literature. Theoretically, because different income groups have different housing demands, changes in income distribution should significantly affect house prices through the amplification effect of credit leverage. Therefore, this paper aims to establish a general framework to interpret house price changes through the channel of income gaps affecting credit constraints. It shows that income gaps, credit constraints, and house prices are closely related. Specifically, an income gap reduction improves the relative income levels of low-income groups, which relaxes their credit constraints for house purchases. The relaxation of credit constraints makes the (aggregate) housing liquidity premium decrease. However, low-income groups have higher housing marginal utility, and access to external financing increases the housing market weight of low-income groups that have rising incomes. Thus, relaxation of credit constraints raises the housing marginal utility for society as a whole, which offsets the negative impact that liquidity premium decreases have on house prices, and ultimately increases house prices overall. This paper's findings are further supported by empirical analysis of cross-country panel data, which shows that the rising share of income going to low-income groups has significantly stronger effects on credit constraints and house prices than does growth in the incomes of high-income groups. This paper makes three main contributions. First, existing explanations of the effects of income gaps on housing prices are mainly based on static analyses; because our model introduces the effects of credit constraints, this paper incorporates dynamic characteristics. Second, previous studies often use representative agent models to investigate the relationships between credit constraints and house prices. This paper enriches the research dimension by including analysis of heterogeneous agents. Third, the literature mainly studies the relationships between income gaps and house prices directly from the empirical level but does not conduct in-depth analysis of the transmission mechanism. In contrast, the construction of this paper's heterogeneous agent model enables a clear description of the transmission mechanisms between income gaps, credit constraints, and house prices. Importantly for policy makers, our results provide new insights into the factors that cause house prices to rise. Finally, this paper has real-world importance. At present, China's real estate market trends are different in first-and second-tier cities than they are in third-and fourth-tier cities. CREIS data show approximately 10% growth in the land supply and transaction volumes of China's first-and second-tier cities in 2020. In contrast, the data show the land supply and transaction volumes of China's third-and fourth-tier cities decreasing by half in the same year. China's real estate market is deeply tied with bank credit, government revenue, and social investment. If the market encounters a sudden and severe decline, it will inevitably lead to serious systemic financial risks. As far as the current situation is concerned, the proposal of “six priorities and stability in six areas” shows the Chinese central government's concern about the population's livelihood, employment, financial stability, and investment expectations. Narrowing the income gap is itself an important means to protect the basic population's livelihood. This paper shows the further importance of narrowing the income gap to expand the scale of society's use of financing, prevent house prices from collapsing, and stabilize investment expectations. With particular relevance to the “Gray Rhino” real estate market, which is characterized by slowing economic growth and exhaustion of land resources, mechanisms should be considered to prevent the systemic financial risks caused by a “hard landing” of the real estate market. Management of the real economic function of the real estate industry is particularly important at present because the industry has the characteristics of large-scale, long industrial chains, growing employment, and increasing fiscal contributions. Relative to some short-term policies, more analysis should be applied to the basic aspects of income distribution and its influence on the domestic market and the domestic economic cycle.
[1]陈斌开和林毅夫,2013,《发展战略、城市化与中国城乡收入差距》,《中国社会科学》第4期,第82~103+207页。 [2]陈斌开、徐帆和谭力,2012,《人口结构转变与中国住房需求:1999—2025——基于人口普查数据的微观实证研究》,《金融研究》第1期,第129~140页。 [3]李实和朱梦冰,2018,《中国经济转型40年中居民收入差距的变动》,《管理世界》第12期,第19~28页。 [4]陆铭、欧海军和陈斌开,2014,《理性还是泡沫:对城市化、移民和房价的经验研究》,《世界经济》第1期,第30~54页。 [5]梅冬州、崔小勇和吴娱,2018,《房价变动、土地财政与中国经济波动》,《经济研究》第1期,第35~49页。 [6]邵朝对、苏丹妮和邓宏图,2016,《房价、土地财政与城市集聚特征:中国式城市发展之路》,《管理世界》第2期,第19~31页。 [7]沈悦和刘洪玉,2004,《住宅价格与经济基本面:1995—2002年中国14城市的实证研究》,《经济研究》第6期,第78~86页。 [8]徐舒和陈珣,2016,《收入差距会推高住房价格吗?》,《经济学(季刊)》第1期,第549~570页。 [9]杨华磊、温兴春和何凌云,2015,《出生高峰、人口结构与住房市场》,《人口研究》第3期,第87~99页。 [10]叶菁菁、余白雪和余建宇,2021,《交易环节税收优惠对住房市场影响:理论和机制检验》,《世界经济》第5期,第154~177页。 [11]张巍、许家云和杨竺松,2018,《房价、工资与资源配置效率——基于微观家庭数据的实证分析》,《金融研究》第8期,第69~84页。 [12]Abebe, H., A. C. Sefa, S. Russell and T. B. Kingsley. 2020. “Income Inequality and Housing Prices in the Very Long-run,” Research Gate Working Paper. [13]Agnello, L. and R. M. Sousa. 2014. “How does Fiscal Consolidation Impact on Income Inequality?” Review of Income and Wealth, 60(4): 702~726. [14]Anari, A. and J. W. Kolari. 2002. “House Prices and Inflation,” Real Estate Economics, 30(1): 67~84. [15]Bauer, G. H. 2017. “International House Price Cycles, Monetary Policy and Credit,” Journal of International Money and Finance, 74(7): 88~114. [16]Beck, T. 2002. “Financial Development and International Trade: Is there a Link?” Journal of International Economics, 57(1): 107~131. [17]Bordo, M. D., and C. M. Meissner. 2012. “Does Inequality Lead to a Financial Crisis?” Journal of International Money and Finance, 31(8): 2147~2161. [18]Davis, M. A. and F. Ortalomagne. 2011. “Household Expenditures, Wages, Rents,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 14(2): 248~261. [19]Goda, T., C. Stewart and A. T. Garcia. 2019. “Absolute Income Inequality and Rising House Prices,” Socio-Economic Review, 6(3): 1~36. [20]Iacoviello, M. 2005. “House Prices, Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle,” American Economic Review, 95(3): 739~764. [21]Kiyotaki, N., and J. Moore. 1997. “Credit Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, 105(2): 211~248. [22]Kumhof, M., R. Ranciere and P. Winant. 2015. “Inequality, Leverage and Crises,” American Economic Review, 105(3): 1217-1245. [23]Liu, Z., P. Wang and T. Zha. 2013. “Land-Price Dynamics and Macroeconomic Fluctuations,” Econometrica, 81(3): 1147~1184. [24]Liu, Z., P. Wang and T. Zha. 2019. “A Theory of Housing Demand Shocks,” NBER Working Paper, No. 25667. [25]Maattanen, N. and M. Tervio. 2014. “Income Distribution and Housing Prices: An Assignment Model Approach,” Journal of Economic Theory, 151(5): 381~410. [26]Malinen, T. 2016. “Does Income Inequality Contribute to Credit Cycles?” Journal of Economic Inequality, 14(3): 309~325. [27]Ortalomagne, F. and R. Sven. 2006. “Housing Market Dynamics: On the Contribution of Income Shocks and Credit Constraints,” Review of Economic Studies, 73(2): 459~485. [28]Özmen, M. U., M. K. Kalafatcilar and E. Yilmaz. 2019. “The Impact of Income Distribution on House Prices,” Central Bank Review, 19(2): 45~58. [29]Piketty, T. 2015. “About Capital in the Twenty-First Century,” American Economic Review, 105(5): 48~53. [30]Solt, F. 2019. “Measuring Income Inequality Across Countries and Over Time: The Standardized World Income Inequality Database (SWIID Version 8.3),” Social Science Quarterly, 101(3):1183~1199. [31]Tsui, W. H. K., D. T. W. Tan and S. Shi. 2017. “Impacts of Airport Traffic Volumes on House Prices of New Zealand's Major Regions: A Panel Data Approach,” Urban Studies, 54(12): 2800~2817. [32]Zhang, C., S. Jia and R. Yang. 2016. “Housing Affordability and Housing Vacancy in China: The Role of Income Inequality,” Journal of Housing Economics, 33(6): 4~14. [33]Zhang, C. 2015. “Income Inequality and Access to Housing: Evidence from China,” China Economic Review, 36(10): 261~271.