Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2021, Vol. 490 Issue (4): 111-130    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
回不去的家乡?——教育公共品供给与人口回流的实证研究
李明, 郑礼明
对外经济贸易大学国际经济贸易学院, 北京 100029
When can I Go Home?School Provisioning and the Decision to Immigrate
LI Ming, ZHENG Liming
School of International Trade and Economics, University of International Business and Economics
下载:  PDF (662KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 随着我国流动人口回流趋势显现以及户籍制度改革深化,如何促进合理、公正、畅通、有序的社会性流动,正成为众多城市思考的重要问题。本文基于2001年起在全国范围内实施的“撤点并校”政策外生冲击,结合2005年全国1%人口抽样调查数据和295个地级市层面特征数据,实证研究了户籍地教育公共品供给状况对流动人口回流决策的影响。研究发现,户籍地教育公共品减少显著阻碍了流动人口回流,减少幅度越大,阻碍越严重。异质性分析结果表明,这种阻碍倾向不分户口类型,但对家中有男孩、家庭规模较小的流动人口更加明显。引入代际视角后的研究结果显示,教育公共品减少增加了流动人口家庭中适龄入学儿童迁出户籍地的概率,教育公共品供给影响两代人的迁移。上述结果意味着,改进公共资源配置效率,提高供给体系质量、优化公共品供给布局,有助于破除劳动力流动障碍,应成为未来城市工作的重要方向。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
李明
郑礼明
关键词:  教育公共品  人口回流  撤点并校  Tiebout机制    
Summary:  In recent years, the existing population of China has begun to relocate among different cities.This is exemplified by a new trend among China's massive migrant population of returning to their hometowns.With the relaxation of the Hukou system, it is worth considering how to promote the reasonable and orderly flow of labor and improve the efficiency of human resource allocation.Many factors influence migration.Tiebout proposed that residents flow into the region that best matches their preferences, after considering the public goods and tax levels of each location.Studies of developed countries suggest that this mechanism exists (Bayoh et al., 2006;Kleven et al., 2013;Dustmann and Okatenko, 2014;Akcigit et al., 2016;Moretti and Wilson, 2017).However, due to the uniform tax system and Hukou system in China, the effectiveness of the Tiebout model is debated, especially in the context of populations returning to their hometowns.
We empirically investigate the causal effect of public goods supply on a migrants' decisions to return to their hometowns.We obtain data on residential address and “usual place of residence five years ago” from the 2005 National Sample Survey to construct a dynamic variable denoting whether migrants return to their hometowns.We also construct a proxy variable for change in the number of schools at the city level according to the extended implementation of the “School Consolidation” policy in China.This is a public policy promoted in China since 2001 that aims to improve the quality of education by eliminating many smaller schools and merging them into larger institutions.Using a quasi-natural experimental approach, we divide the sample into treat and control groups based on the presence of children aged 6-10 years in the family (a child was 10 years old in 2005 when the data was collected, given that he/she started primary school at 6 years of age in 2001) and build a difference-in-differences model.
Our findings are as follows.First, a decrease in the number of schools significantly hinders the return of the migrant population.Furthermore, the greater the decrease in the number of schools, the greater the negative impact on the return of the migrant population.This result still holds when considering endogeneity and other factors.Second, the results of our heterogeneity analysis show that the impact above is valid for both rural and urban areas and is more obvious among smaller families and families with boys.Third, the impact is not only on parents but also on their school-age children, meaning that the availability of educational public goods affects the migration decisions of two generations.
Beyond confirming the Tiebout model, this paper contributes to the literature in at least in two additional ways.First, we demonstrate the impact of public goods on migrants returning home and enrich the literature in this field.Most existing studies exploring the impact of public services on migration are based on an outflow perspective, and little attention has been paid to returning inflows.Further, due to limited data, the available studies are more theoretical in nature.Second, our identification setup is new.We attempt to explore the dynamics of migration based on cross-sectional census data at the household level, which may inform future studies.
The conclusions of this paper are informative in the context of policy decisions.In developing countries, improving the efficiency of public resource distribution and optimizing the provision of public goods such as education could help break down barriers to labor mobility and thus further promote economic growth and quality of life.For cities trying to attract talent, enhancing the provisioning of public goods could help to stimulate further population inflows.In this paper, we focus on the impact of changes in the number of schools.Future studies could assess the impacts of public education quality or other public goods (e.g., health care) to explore the effect of public goods supply on population mobility to a broader and deeper extent.
Keywords:  School Provisioning    Immigration    School Consolidation    Tiebout Model
JEL分类号:  H41   H31   J61  
基金资助: * 本文感谢国家社科基金重大项目(项目号:19ZDA072)和北京市社科基金青年项目(项目号:19YJC027)的资助。感谢匿名审稿人的宝贵意见,文责自负。
通讯作者:  郑礼明,经济学博士研究生,对外经济贸易大学国际经济贸易学院,E-mail:zhliming15@163.com.   
作者简介:  李 明,经济学博士,教授,对外经济贸易大学国际经济贸易学院,E-mail:lamenfdren@126.com.
引用本文:    
李明, 郑礼明. 回不去的家乡?——教育公共品供给与人口回流的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 490(4): 111-130.
LI Ming, ZHENG Liming. When can I Go Home?School Provisioning and the Decision to Immigrate. Journal of Financial Research, 2021, 490(4): 111-130.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2021/V490/I4/111
[1] 丁冬和郑风田,2015,《撤点并校:整合教育资源还是减少教育投入?—基于1996—2009年的省级面板数据分析》,《经济学(季刊)》第14卷第2期,第603~622页。
[2] 丁延庆、王绍达和叶晓阳,2016,《为什么有些地方政府撤并了更多农村学校》,《教育经济评论》第1卷第4期,第3~34页。
[3] 付文林,2007,《人口流动的结构性障碍:基于公共支出竞争的经验分析》,《世界经济》第12期,第32~40页。
[4] 黎嘉辉,2019,《城市房价、公共品与流动人口留城意愿》,《财经研究》第6期,第86~100页。
[5] 李斌、李拓和朱业,2015,《公共服务均等化、民生财政支出与城市化—基于中国286个城市面板数据的动态空间计量检验》,《中国软科学》第6期,第79~90页。
[6] 李超、万海远和田志磊,2018,《为教育而流动—随迁子女教育政策改革对农民工流动的影响》,《财贸经济》第1期,第132~146页。
[7] 李明和张亦然,2019,《空气污染的移民效应—基于来华留学生高校-城市选择的研究》,《经济研究》第6期,第168~182页。
[8] 梁超和王素素,2020,《教育公共品配置调整对人力资本的影响——基于撤点并校的研究》,《经济研究》第9期,第138~154页。
[9] 梁若冰和汤韵,2008,《地方公共品供给中的Tiebout模型—基于中国城市房价的经验研究》,《世界经济》第10期,第71~83页。
[10] 卢珂和杜育红,2010,《农村学校布局调整对学生成绩的影响—基于两水平增值模型的分析》,《清华大学教育研究》第31卷第6期,第64~73页。
[11] 陆铭、高虹和佐藤宏,2012,《城市规模与包容性就业》,《中国社会科学》第10期,第47~66页。
[12] 乔宝云、范剑勇和冯兴元,2005,《中国的财政分权与小学义务教育》,《中国社会科学》第6期,第37~46页。
[13] 宋弘和吴茂华,2020,《高房价是否导致了区域高技能人力资本流出?》,《金融研究》第3期,第77~95页。
[14] 汪德华、邹杰和毛中根,2019,《“扶教育之贫”的增智与增收效应—对20世纪90年代“国家贫困地区义务教育工程”的评估》,《经济研究》第9期,第155~171页。
[15] 吴伟平和刘乃全,2016,《异质性公共支出对劳动力迁移的门槛效应:理论模型与经验分析》,《财贸经济》第3期,第28~44页。
[16] 夏纪军,2004,《人口流动性、公共收入与支出—户籍制度变迁动因分析》,《经济研究》第10期,第56~65页。
[17] 夏怡然和陆铭,2015,《城市间的“孟母三迁”—公共服务影响劳动力流向的经验研究》,《管理世界》第10期,第78~90页。
[18] 邢春冰和李实,2011,《扩招“大跃进”、教育机会与大学毕业生就业》,《经济学(季刊)》第10卷第4期,第1187~1208页。
[19] 张晏、夏纪军和张文瑾,2010,《自上而下的标尺竞争与中国省级政府公共支出溢出效应差异》,《浙江社会科学》第12期,第20~26+74页。
[20] 周黎安,2007,《中国地方官员的晋升锦标赛模式研究》,《经济研究》第7期,第36~50页。
[21] Aaronson, D.and B.Mazumder, 2011, “The Impact of Rosenwald Schools on Black Achievement ”, Journal of Political Economy, 119(5): 821~888.
[22] Akcigit, U., S.Baslandze and S.Stantcheva, 2016, “Taxation and the International Mobility of Inventors”, American Economic Review, 106(10): 2930~2981.
[23] Angrist, J.D.and V.Lavy, 1999, “Using Maimonides' Rule to Estimate the Effect of Class Size on Scholastic Achievement ”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(2): 533~575.
[24] Bayoh, I., E.Irwin and T.Haab, 2006, “Determinants of Residential Location Choice: How Important are Local Public Goods in Attracting Homeowners to Central City Locations? ”, Journal of Regional Science, 46(1): 97~120.
[25] Conley, T.G., C.B.Hansen and P.E.Rossi, 2012, “Plausibly Exogenous”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(1): 260~272.
[26] Dahlberg, M., M.Eklof, P.Fredriksson and J.Jofremonseny, 2012, “Estimating Preferences for Local Public Services Using Migration Data”, Urban Studies, 49(2): 319~336.
[27] Day, K.M., 1992, “Interprovincial Migration and Local Public Goods”, The Canadian Journal of Economics, 25(1): 123~144.
[28] Duflo, E., 2001, “Schooling and Labor Market Consequences of School Construction in Indonesia: Evidence from an Unusual Policy Experiment”, American Economic Review, 91(4): 795~813.
[29] Dustmann, C.and A.Okatenko, 2014, “Out-Migration, Wealth Constraints, and The Quality of Local Amenities”, Journal of Development Economics, 110: 52~63.
[30] Kleven, H.J., C.Landais and E.Saez, 2013, “Taxation and International Migration of Superstars: Evidence from the European Football Market”, American Economic Review, 103(5): 1892~1924.
[31] Kleven, H.J., C.Landais, E.Saez and E.A.Schultz, 2014, “Migration and Wage Effects of Taxing Top Earners: Evidence from the Foreigners' Tax Scheme in Denmark”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(1): 333~378.
[32] Krueger, A.B., 1999, “Experimental Estimates of Education Production Functions”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(2): 497~532.
[33] Liu, J.and C.Xing, 2016, “Migrate for Education: An Unintended Effect of School District Combination in Rural China”, China Economic Review, 40: 192~206.
[34] Liu, Q.and Y.Lu, 2015, “Firm Investment and Exporting: Evidence from China's Value-added Tax Reform ”, Journal of International Economics, 97(2): 392~403.
[35] Moretti, E.and D.J.Wilson, 2017, “The Effect of State Taxes on the Geographical Location of Top Earners: Evidence from Star Scientists”, American Economic Review, 107(7): 1858~1903.
[36] Nunn, N.and L.Wantchekon, 2011, “The Slave Trade and the Origins of Mistrust in Africa”, American Economic Review, 101(7): 3221~3252.
[1] 王小龙, 陈金皇. 省直管县改革与区域空气污染——来自卫星反演数据的实证证据[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 485(11): 76-93.
[2] 杨国超, 盘宇章. 信任被定价了吗? ——来自债券市场的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 463(1): 35-53.
[3] 刘勇政, 李岩. 中国的高速铁路建设与城市经济增长[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 18-33.
[4] 卢洪友, 余锦亮, 张楠. 纵向行政管理结构与地方政府财政支出规模[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 448(10): 35-51.
[5] 王兵, 聂欣. 经济发展的健康成本:污水排放与农村中老年健康[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 429(3): 59-73.
[1] 邓路, 刘瑞琪, 江萍. 公司超额银行借款会导致过度投资吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 448(10): 115 -129 .
[2] 江娇, 刘红忠, 曾剑平. 中国股票网络论坛的信息含量分析段[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 448(10): 178 -192 .
[3] 梁巨方, 韩乾. 商品期货可以提供潜在组合多样化收益吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 446(8): 129 -144 .
[4] 张晓宇, 徐龙炳. 限售股解禁、资本运作与股价崩盘风险[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 449(11): 158 -174 .
[5] 李少昆. 美国货币政策是全球发展中经济体外汇储备影响因素吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 448(10): 68 -82 .
[6] 郭晔, 黄振, 王蕴. 未预期货币政策与企业债券信用利差——基于固浮利差分解的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 432(6): 67 -80 .
[7] 严成樑. 延迟退休、财政支出结构调整与养老金替代率[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 447(9): 51 -66 .
[8] 杨晓兰, 金雪军. 我国股票市场熔断机制的磁力效应:基于自然实验的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 447(9): 161 -177 .
[9] 戴严科, 林曙. 利率波动、融资约束与存货投资——来自中国制造业企业的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 442(4): 95 -111 .
[10] 谢平, 邹传伟, 刘海二. 互联网金融的基础理论[J]. 金融研究, 2015, 422(8): 1 -12 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1