Summary:
The Central Financial Work Conference of 2023 proposes that efforts should be made to promote high-level financial opening-up, ensure financial and economic national security, and accelerate the construction of a financial power. In recent years, cross-border capital flows have become more frequent, and there is an obvious global financial cycle. Simultaneously, the relationship between cross-border capital flows and credit fluctuations in various countries has become closer. Historical experiences indicate that credit booms often precede financial disturbances like banking crises. In fact, exchange rates are crucial in linking cross-border capital flows, domestic credit cycles, and banking crises. Classical international finance theories suggest that under free capital flows, a floating exchange rate regime can stabilize external shocks and ensure the independence of central bank monetary policies. Under the background of global financial cycles, scholars have engaged in hot discussions about whether floating exchange rate regimes act as stabilizers and how China should choose its exchange rate regime and pursue high-quality financial opening-up. However, they have not yet reached a consensus. Therefore, it is necessary to explore the relationship among cross-border capital flows, domestic credit cycles, and banking crises under different exchange rate regimes. It could not only enhance international financial theories and provide empirical guidance for the reform of the RMB exchange rate regime, but also could act as a key element in promoting the process of high-quality financial opening-up and ensuring no systemic risks arise. This paper collects domestic credit and cross-border capital flow data from 28 emerging market economies, sourced from the International Monetary Fund and the Bank for International Settlements. The paper divides credit booms and busts, constructs a Probit regression model to study the empirical relationship between cross-border capital inflows and domestic credit booms or busts, and focuses on whether a floating exchange rate regime can act as a stabilizer. We find that non-direct investment debt inflows, especially cross-border bank loan inflows, exhibit a pro-cyclical relationship with domestic credit. Compared to fixed exchange rate regimes, the pro-cyclical relationship between cross-border bank loan inflows and domestic credit weakens in countries with floating exchange rate regimes, indicating that floating exchange rates play a stabilizing role. However, the pro-cyclical relationship between bond inflows and domestic credit strengthens under floating exchange rate regimes. Further analysis indicates that floating exchange rates can stabilize “good booms” that do not trigger banking crises but cannot suppress “bad booms” that end with banking crises. Thus, floating exchange rate regimes need to be coordinated with other policies, such as tight macroprudential policies, to effectively curb the occurrence of banking crises. This paper makes the following contributions: First, unlike existing studies that consider how capital inflows affect credit growth or analyze how capital inflows affect credit cycles from the perspective of debt structures, this paper analyzes the relationship among cross-border capital inflows, domestic credit cycles, and banking crises within a unified framework. More importantly, this paper studies the relationship among these three elements from the perspective of exchange rate regimes, investigating whether floating exchange rate regimes can act as stabilizers. Second, existing research rarely explores the relationship between different types of capital inflows and domestic credit fluctuations according to debt types and borrowing sectors. Avdjiev et al. (2021) found that domestic credit cycles are related to the type of external debt and borrowing sectors but did not further explore whether credit booms triggered by different types and sectors have different impacts on banking crises, and also did not investigate the role of floating exchange rate regimes. This paper finds that the stabilizing role of floating exchange rate regimes depends on the type and borrowing sectors. Third, existing literature has not explored the role of exchange rate regimes in stabilizing different types of credit booms and in preventing crises. This paper finds that floating exchange rate regimes can only stabilize “good booms” but cannot stabilize “bad booms” that lead to crises. Cooperation with other policies (such as macroprudential policies) is needed to better play the stabilizing role, indicating that floating exchange rate regimes are not a “one-size-fits-all” solution. Based on these conclusions, this paper has the following policy implications: First, emerging market economies should closely monitor and avoid large-scale cross-border bank loan flows. Second, in the process of promoting financial opening-up and maintaining financial stability, each department should effectively guard against exchange rate risks and choose reasonable external financing methods. When increasing domestic non-banking sector financing through the international bond market, the cost of managing exchange rate risks for the non-banking sector should be reduced through improving financial infrastructure. Third, emerging market economies need to strike a balance in the choice of exchange rate regimes while promoting financial opening-up and maintaining financial stability. Crawling peg regimes and managed floating regimes may be better choices. Fourth, exchange rate regimes themselves have limited effectiveness in preventing systemic financial risks. While maintaining a dual fluctuation of exchange rates, regulators should strengthen macroprudential supervision of the banking sector.
[1]刘元春和林垚,2020,《“不可能三角”还是“不可能二元”——评述传统开放宏观理论面临的新挑战》,《国际金融研究》第7期,第3~12页。 [2]芦东、刘家琳和周行,2021,《浮动汇率制能有效降低跨境资本流动波动吗?》,《国际金融研究》第11期,第43~54页。 [3]梅冬州和龚六堂,2011,《新兴市场经济国家的汇率制度选择》,《经济研究》第11期,第73~88页。 [4]彭红枫、肖祖沔和祝小全,2018,《汇率市场化与资本账户开放的路径选择》,《世界经济》第8期,第26~50页。 [5]谭小芬、曹倩倩、苟琴和李想,2023,《美元汇率对企业投资的影响及其传导机制》,《财贸经济》第3期,第55~70页。 [6]张礼卿和钟茜,2020,《全球金融周期、美国货币政策与“三元悖论”》,《金融研究》第2期,第15~33页。 [7]Araujo, J., A. David, C. van Hombeeck and C.Papageorgiou, 2017a, “Joining the Club? Procyclicality of Private Capital Inflows in Lower Income Developing Countries”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 70. pp.157~182. [8]Avdjiev, S., S. Binder and R. Sousa, 2021, “External Debt Composition and Domestic Credit Cycles”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 115, 102377. [9]Balloch, C.M., 2018, “Inflows and Spillovers: Tracing the Impact of Bond Market Liberalization”, Unpublished Working Paper, Columbia University. [10]Barajas, A., G. Dell’Ariccia and A. Levchenko, 2009, “Credit Booms: The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly”, Washington, DC: IMF, manuscript. [11]Blanchard, O., 2021, “Currency Wars, Coordination, and Capital Controls”, In The Asian Monetary Policy Forum: Insights for Central Banking, pp.134~157. [12]Blanchard, O., J. D. Ostry, A. R. Ghosh and M. Chamon,2017, “Are Capital Inflows Expansionary or Contractionary? Theory, Policy Implications, and Some Evidence”, IMF Economic Review, 3, pp.563~585. [13]Bruno, V. and H. S. Shin, 2015b, “Cross-Border Banking and Global Liquidity”, The Review of Economic Studies, 82, pp.535~564. [14]Bruno, V. and H. S. Shin, 2023, “Dollar and Exports”, The Review of Financial Studies, 36(8), pp.2963~2996. [15]Caballero, J. A., 2016. “Do Surges in International Capital Inflows Influence the Likelihood of Banking Crises?”, The Economic Journal, 126(591), pp. 281~316. [16]Ca' Zorzi, M., L. Dedola, G. Georgiadis, M. Jarocinski, L. Stracca and G. Strasser, 2020, “Monetary Policy and its Transmission in A Globalised World”, ECB Working Papers, No.2407. [17]Calderon, C. and M. Kubota, 2012, “Gross Inflows Gone Wild: Gross Capital Inflows, Credit Booms and Crises”, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No.6270. [18]Calvo, G., 2012a, “Financial Crises and Liquidity Shocks: A Bank‐Run Perspective”, European Economic Review, 56(3), pp.317~26. [19]Chari, A. and P. B. Henry, 2004, “Risk Sharing and Asset Prices: Evidence from A Natural Experiment”, The Journal of Finance, 59(3), pp.1295~1324. [20]Giovanni, D. J., S. Kalemli-Özcan, M. F. Ulu and Y. S. Baskaya, 2022, “International Spillovers and Local Credit Cycles”, The Review of Economic Studies, 89(2), pp.733~773. [21]Fernández, A., M. W. Klein, A. Rebucci, M. Schindle and M. Uribe, 2016, “Capital Control Measures: A New Dataset”, IMF Economic Review, 64, pp.548~574. [22]Gertler, M., N. Kiyotaki and A. Prestipino, 2020b, “Credit Booms, Financial Crises, and Macroprudential Policy”, Review of Economic Dynamics, 37, pp. S8~S33. [23]Ghosh, A. R., M. S. Qureshi, J. I., Kim and J. Zalduendo, 2014, “Surges”, Journal of International Economics, 92, pp.266~285. [24]Ghosh, A. R., J. Ostry and M. Qureshi, 2015, “Exchange Rate Management and Crisis Susceptibility: A Reassessment”, IMF Economic Review, 63, pp.238~276. [25]Gorton, G. and G. Ordonez, 2020, “Good Booms, Bad Booms”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 18(2), pp.618~665. [26]Gourinchas, P. O., 2018, “Monetary Policy Transmission in Emerging Markets: an Application to Chile”, Series on Central Banking Analysis and Economic Policies, No. 25. [27]Gourinchas, P. O. and M. Obstfeld, 2012, “Stories of the Twentieth Century for the Twenty-First”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 4(1), pp.226~65. [28]Grintzalis, I., D. Lodge and A. S. Manu, 2017, “The Implications of Global and Domestic Credit Cycles for Emerging Market Economies: Measures of Finance-Adjusted Output Gaps”, ECB Working Paper, No.2034. [29]Hahm, Joon-Ho, H. S. Shin and K. Shin, 2013, “Non-Core Bank Liabilities and Financial Vulnerability”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 45, pp.3~36. [30]Han, X., and S. J. Wei, 2018, “International Transmissions of Monetary Shocks: Between a Trilemma and a Dilemma”, Journal of International Economics, 110, pp.205~219. [31]Huang, Y., U. Panizza and R. Portes, 2018, “Corporate Foreign Bond Issuance and Interfirm Loans in China”, NBER Working Paper, No. 24513. [32]Ilzetzki E., C. M. Reinhart and K. S. Rogoff, 2019, “Exchange Arrangements Entering the Twenty-First Century:Which Anchor Will Hold?”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 134(2), pp.599~646. [33]Kalemli-Özcan, S., 2019, “US Monetary Policy and International Risk Spillovers”, NBER Working Paper, No. w26297. [34]Laeven, L. and F. Valencia, 2020, “Systemic Banking Crises Database II”, IMF Economic Review, 2, pp.307~361. [35]Lane, P. R. and P. McQuade, 2014, “Domestic Credit Growth and International Capital Flows”, The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 1, pp.218~252. [36]Magud, N. E., C. M. Reinhart and E. R. Vesperoni, 2014, “Capital Inflowis, Exchange Rate Flexibility and Credit Booms”, Review of Development Economics, 3, pp.415~430. [37]Miranda-Agrippino, S., and H. Rey, 2022, “The Global Financial Cycle”, In Handbook of international economics, 6, pp.1~43. [38]Obstfeld, M., J. D. Ostry and M. S., Qureshi, 2019, “A Tie that Binds: Revisiting the Trilemma in Emerging Market Economies”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 101, pp.279~293. [39]Passari, E. and H. Rey, 2015, “Financial Flows and the International Monetary System”, The Economic Journal, 125, pp.675~698. [40]Quinn, D. and A. Toyoda, 2008, “Does Capital Account Liberalization Lead to Economic Growth?”, Review of Financial Studies, 21, pp.1403~1449. [41]Reinhart, C. M. and V. R. Reinhart, 2009, “Capital Flow Bonanzas: An Encompassing View of the Past and Present”, The University of Chicago Press. [42]Rey, H., 2015, “Dilemma not Trilemma: The Global Financial Cycle and Monetary Policy Independence”, NBER Working Paper, No. w21162. [43]Schularick, M. and A. M. Taylor, 2012, “Credit Booms Gone Bust: Monetary Policy, Leverage Cycles, and Financial Crises, 1870-2008”, American Economic Review, 102(2), pp.1029~1061. [44]Shambaugh, J., 2004, “The Effect of Fixed Exchange Rates on Monetary Policy”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(1), pp.301~352. [45]Wu, J. C. and F. D. Xia, 2016, “Measuring the Macroeconomic Impact of Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 48, pp.253~291.