Summary:
Understanding the drivers of China's cross-border capital flows is critical for maintaining financial stability and curbing financial risks in China. Cross-border flows are generally driven by both push and pull factors. Conventional wisdom holds that these can be best captured by interest rate differentials across countries. However, interest rate differentials are not the only driver of China's cross-border flows. Empirical studies suggest that speculation on potential price movements in bilateral exchange rates (i.e., currency speculation) is also an important motivation. In history, as both the interest rate and the RMB exchange rate are not fully market-driven in China, there may be other factors that have affected China's cross-border flows. To shed light on this important issue, we focus on the role of the U.S. dollar index (DXY). Leveraging the time-varying parameter vector auto-regression (TVPVAR) method, we find that the DXY is the most critical factor in determining China's cross-border flows. This finding is robust to a variety of sample periods and model specifications. Why is the exchange rate more important than the interest rate? And why is the multilateral dollar exchange rate more critical than the bilateral exchange rate of the RMB against the U.S. dollar? We refer these questions as “the conundrum of China's cross-border capital flows.” To resolve this conundrum, we examine the channels through which the DXY affects capital flows and propose a novel framework to explain China's cross-border flows. Our empirical results suggest that the DXY influences capital flows through two main channels. The first is via exchange rate expectations. For a long period, the RMB exchange rate was either pegged or crawling pegged to the U.S. dollar, resulting in the low flexibility of the RMB. In this condition, when factors other than China's economic fundamentals make the U.S. dollar appreciate, the RMB is expected to depreciate, which leads to the outflow of speculative capital. Similarly, when the U.S. dollar depreciates, the RMB is expected to appreciate, which attracts capital flows. Therefore, when the bilateral RMB exchange rate against the U.S. dollar cannot make timely adjustments based on fundamentals, the DXY becomes a leading indicator of RMB exchange rate expectations, thereby driving capital flows. The second channel is through risk appetite. Studies document that the U.S. dollar cycle is highly correlated with the global risk appetite and the DXY is becoming the best representation of global investors' risk appetite. As the world's most important financing currency, the value of the U.S. dollar affects the willingness and ability of major global financial institutions to provide liquidity through the balance sheet effect. If the DXY drives China's cross-border capital flows, what drives the DXY? Our results show that the China-U.S. interest rate differential increasingly explains and even leads the DXY. The China-U.S. interest rate differential first and foremost reflects the differentiation of the economic fundamentals of the two economies. As China's spillovers become stronger, however, the China-U.S. differential also drives and reflects economic differentiation between the U.S. and other major economies, including Europe and Japan. Accordingly, the China-U.S. interest rate differential could still explain and lead the DXY, despite the index not including the RMB. Our most critical contributions are uncovering a novel factor that determines China's capital flows—the DXY—and showing that it is more important than interest rate differentials. However, we also find that China-U.S. interest rate differentials can explain the DXY. The explanation for these seemingly contradictory findings lies in the historical inflexibility of the RMB’s bilateral exchange rate, which does not fully reflect shifts in economic fundamentals in a timely and adequate manner. This lagging and insufficient response can be corrected through two channels. One channel is through capital flows driven by interest rate differentials, a traditional channel frequently highlighted in the literature and by policymakers. We emphasize a brand new and more critical channel: the exchange rate speculation channel arising from the lack of exchange rate flexibility.China's economy drives the DXY due to its increasing spillovers to Europe and Japan. The DXY in turn drives China's cross-border flows by affecting exchange rate expectations and global risk appetite. When changes in the bilateral exchange rate are lagging and insufficient, currency speculation and changes in risk appetite could lead to large and volatile capital flows. Therefore, increasing exchange rate flexibility would not only increase monetary policy independence but also significantly reduce the overshooting of capital flows.
[1] 陈创练,姚树洁,郑挺国和欧璟华,2017,《利率市场化, 汇率改制与国际资本流动的关系研究》,《经济研究》第4期,第64~77页。 [2] 方先明,裴平和张谊浩,2012,《国际投机资本流入: 动机与冲击——基于中国大陆1999—2011年样本数据的实证检验》,《金融研究》第1期,第65~77页。 [3] 缪延亮和郝阳,2017,《人民币汇率机制和预期》,工作论文。 [4] 缪延亮,郝阳和杨媛媛,2021,《外汇储备、全球流动性与汇率的决定》,《经济研究》第8期,即将刊登(更早版本见于2019年《经济研究》工作论文)。 [5] 缪延亮和饶璨,2016,《中国企业外债知多少:一个更新》,《新金融评论》第4期,第24~39页。 [6] 王世华和何帆,2007,《中国的短期国际资本流动:现状、流动途径和影响因素》,《世界经济》第7期,第12~19页。 [7] 吴丽华和傅广敏,2014,《人民币汇率、短期资本与股价互动》,《经济研究》第11期,第72~86页。 [8] 徐苏江,2016,《英美及我国外汇市场结构的比较分析》,《新金融》第1期,第21~26页。 [9] 张明和谭小芬,2013,《中国短期资本流动的主要驱动因素:2000-2012》,《世界经济》第11期,第93~116页。 [10] 赵进文和张敬思,2013,《人民币汇率、短期国际资本流动与股票价格——基于汇改后数据的再检验》,《金融研究》第1期,第9~23页。 [11] Ahmed, S. and Zlate, A., 2014. “Capital flows to emerging market economies: A brave new world?”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 48:221~248. [12] Avdjiev, S., Bruno, V., Koch, C., and Shin, H. S. 2019(a). “The dollar exchange rate as a global risk factor: evidence from investment”, IMF Economic Review, 67(1):151~173. [13] Avdjiev, S., Du, W., Koch, C., and Shin, H. S. 2019(b). “The dollar, bank leverage, and deviations from covered interest parity”, American Economic Review: Insights, 1(2):193~208. [14] Brunnermeier, M.K., Nagel, S. and Pedersen, L.H. 2008. “Carry trades and currency crashes”, NBER macroeconomics annual, 23(1):313~348. [15] Cerutti, E., Claessens, S. and Puy, D. 2019. “Push factors and capital flows to emerging markets: why knowing your lender matters more than fundamentals”, Journal of international economics, 119:133~149. [16] Engel C. 2016. “Exchange rates, interest rates, and the risk premium”, American Economic Review, 106(2):436~74. [17] Fern'andez-Arias, E. 1996. “The new wave of private capital inflows: push or pull?”, Journal of Development Economics, 48(2):389~418. [18] Gabaix X, and Maggiori M. 2015. “International Liquidity and Exchange Rate Dynamics”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 130(3):1369~1420. [19] Jonen, B., and Scheuring, S. 2014. “Time-varying international diversification and the forward premium”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 40:128~148. [20] Koepke R. 2018. “Fed policy expectations and portfolio flows to emerging markets”. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, 55:170~194. [21] Nakajima, J. 2011. “Time-varying parameter VAR model with stochastic volatility: An overview of methodology and empirical applications”, (No. 11-E-09). Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan. [22] Primiceri, G. E. 2005. “Time varying structural vector autoregressions and monetary policy”, The Review of Economic Studies, 72(3):821~852.