Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2025, Vol. 543 Issue (9): 39-57    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
全球价值链位置如何影响出口价格汇率传递
江春, 孙福伟, 刘赛红
武汉大学经济与管理学院,湖北武汉 430000;
湖南工商大学财政金融学院,湖南长沙 410006
How Does A Firm's Position in the Global Value Chain Affect Exchange Rate Pass-Through to Export Prices?
JIANG Chun, SUN Fuwei, LIU Saihong
School of Economics and Management, Wuhan University;
School of Finance, Hunan University of Technology and Business
下载:  PDF (785KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 在人民币汇率市场化改革与全球价值链重构协同演进的背景下,出口企业在全球价值链中面临的汇率风险备受关注。本文将全球价值链出口—进口双维度位置特征纳入企业定价模型,系统考察全球价值链位置对汇率传递的影响机制,并采用中国出口至172个国家的4038类产品数据进行实证检验。研究发现:(1)企业向全球价值链上游攀升能够显著降低汇率变动对外币出口价格的传递程度,且相比进口位置,出口位置攀升的影响更为显著。(2)出口位置主要通过市场竞争效应直接影响企业定价能力,进口位置则主要通过成本节约效应间接影响企业价格调整空间。(3)核心产品占比高以及累积贸易成本低的企业表现出更低的汇率传递率。本研究从微观层面拓展了不同类型企业视角下的汇率传递理论,为深化人民币汇率市场化改革、实现对外贸易高质量稳定发展提供了有益启示。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
江春
孙福伟
刘赛红
关键词:  全球价值链位置  上游度  汇率传递  出口价格    
Summary:  Exchange rate pass-through (ERPT) is a key mechanism in open economies, profoundly influencing firms' pricing behavior, international competitiveness, and macroeconomic stability. It has long drawn significant attention from both scholars and policymakers. Existing studies indicate that emerging economies generally face high levels of ERPT, with China being particularly notable with almost full pass-through. This implies that fluctuations in the RMB exchange rate are almost fully transmitted to foreign-currency export prices, leaving firms with limited pricing autonomy to buffer external shocks. In this context, while advancing RMB exchange rate marketization could enhance resource allocation efficiency, the persistently high pass-through rate intensifies concerns over the so-called “floating fear”, which means the risk of greater exchange rate flexibility may amplify macroeconomic volatility, thereby constraining deeper reform.
As global value chains (GVCs) have become the dominant mode of international trade, accounting for approximately 60% of global trade, firms increasingly operate as both importers and exporters. Their structural position within GVCs has thus emerged as a critical determinant of pricing decisions. However, much of the existing literature reduces GVC position to a single export dimension, overlooking the joint role of dual positions (import and export) along the full “import-processing-export” chain. This simplification limits our understanding of firms' actual risk-mitigation strategies and leaves key questions unanswered: Under GVC-based production networks, how does the dual identity of firms as both exporters and importers affect their pricing responses to exchange rate fluctuations? Do export and import positions operate through distinct mechanisms? Addressing these questions not only deepens our understanding of micro-level pricing dynamics but also offers theoretical support for overcoming the impasse in exchange rate reform and achieving high-quality foreign trade development.
To answer these questions, this paper extends the heterogeneous-firm pricing model of Berman et al. (2012) by incorporating the dual dimensions of GVC position including export upstreamness and import upstreamness, and develops a theoretical framework with testable hypotheses. The model predicts two distinct channels: First, higher export upstreamness enhances firms' market power and pricing flexibility through a market competition effect, enabling them to absorb exchange rate shocks more effectively and thereby reducing ERPT. Second, higher import upstreamness lowers cumulative trade costs through a cost-saving effect, expanding the margin within which firms can adjust prices, which also dampens ERPT. While both dimensions reduce pass-through, they operate through fundamentally different mechanisms.
Empirically, we test these predictions using a rich, firm-product-destination-year panel dataset from Chinese customs for the period 2000-2016, covering 188,000 firms, 4,038 product categories, and 172 export markets. Our findings are as follows: First, the degree of ERPT from RMB exchange rate changes to export price denominated in forein currency is as high as 91% over the sample period, implying the effectiveness of the expenditure-switching effect. Second, moving up the GVC significantly reduces ERPT, but the marginal effect of export upstreamness is stronger than that of import upstreamness. When both export and import upstreamness are at the 95th percentile, ERPT declines to 79%. Third, mechanism tests support the theoretical predictions: Export upstreamness primarily affects pricing strategies directly through the market competition channel, while import upstreamness operates indirectly by expanding price adjustment space via the cost-saving channel. Fourth, heterogeneous analyses reveal that firms with a higher share of core products or lower cumulative trade costs exhibit greater pricing flexibility and lower ERPT in response to exchange rate fluctuations.
This study makes three main contributions. First, it moves beyond the conventional unidimensional treatment of GVC position by decomposing it into dual dimensions—export and import upstreamness—and identifies two distinct transmission channels: the market competition effect and the cost-saving effect. Second, it quantifies the differential marginal effects of export and import positions, demonstrating the dominant role of export upstreamness in shaping pricing behavior. Third, it constructs a firm-level measure of cumulative trade costs, providing micro-level evidence for the amplification effect of GVC integration.
From a policy perspective, this paper offers two key implications. First, GVC upgrading should be integrated into the broader strategy of RMB exchange rate marketization. As firms move upstream in GVCs, enhanced pricing power and optimized cost structures can reduce ERPT, thereby breaking the path dependency of “stabilizing the exchange rate to stabilize exports” and creating a favorable micro-foundation for further exchange rate liberalization. Second, high-quality foreign trade development should shift from scale expansion to structural upgrading. Policies should focus on fostering core technologies, enhancing the competitiveness of core products, and reducing trade barriers for intermediate goods, encouraging firms to transition from low-value contract manufacturing to high-pricing-power, low-pass-through autonomous models, thereby supporting China's evolution from a “trading giant” to a “trading power”.
Future research could extend this analysis to regional value chains, exploring how GVC positioning within different regional production networks affects ERPT. Such work would provide more targeted policy insights for the international dimension of China's “dual-circulation” development strategy.
Keywords:  Global Value Chain Position    Upstreamness    Exchange Rate Pass-throuh    Export Price
JEL分类号:  F31   F15   F12  
基金资助: *本文感谢国家社会科学基金项目(20BJL062)的资助。感谢匿名审稿人的宝贵意见,文责自负。
通讯作者:  孙福伟,金融学博士,讲师,湖南工商大学财政金融学院,E-mail: flysunhappy@163.com.   
作者简介:  江 春,经济学博士,教授,武汉大学经济与管理学院,E-mail: jiachun@whu.edu.cn.
刘赛红,管理科学工程博士,教授,湖南工商大学财政金融学院,E-mail: lsh8689219@163.com.
引用本文:    
江春, 孙福伟, 刘赛红. 全球价值链位置如何影响出口价格汇率传递[J]. 金融研究, 2025, 543(9): 39-57.
JIANG Chun, SUN Fuwei, LIU Saihong. How Does A Firm's Position in the Global Value Chain Affect Exchange Rate Pass-Through to Export Prices?. Journal of Financial Research, 2025, 543(9): 39-57.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2025/V543/I9/39
[1]曹伟、言方荣和鲍曙明,2016,《人民币汇率变动、邻国效应与双边贸易——基于中国与“一带一路”沿线国家空间面板模型的实证研究》,《金融研究》第9期,第50~66页。
[2]鲁晓东、刘京军和陈芷君,2019,《出口商如何对冲汇率风险:一个价值链整合的视角》,《管理世界》第5期,第92~105页、125页。
[3]倪红福,2020,《全球价值链中的累积关税成本率及结构:理论与实证》,《经济研究》第10期,第89~105页。
[4]宁密密和綦建红,2021,《企业全球价值链位置与“汇率不相关之谜”——基于汇率传递效应的视角》,《国际金融研究》第3期,第87~96页。
[5]孙福伟和江春,2023,《全球价值链嵌入如何影响出口价格汇率传递——基于中国微观经验数据》,《国际金融研究》第9期,第3~15页。
[6]王雅琦、王瑶和张礼卿,2023,《汇率波动对出口稳定的影响:中间品进口的作用》,《金融研究》第1期,第75~93页。
[7]印梅和钱燕,2022,《汇率弹性弱化的一个解释:价值链位置视角》,《世界经济研究》第8期,第56~70页、136页。
[8]曾利飞、蒋凯和曹伟,2023,《中国出口产品质量、汇率传递与出口定价能力——基于出口目的国收入分布视角》,《金融研究》第6期,第75~93页。
[9]Ahmed, S., M. Appendino and M. Ruta, 2015, “Depreciations without Exports? Global Value Chains and the Exchange Rate Elasticity of Exports,” Policy Research Working Papers, The World Bank.
[10]Amiti, M., O. Itskhoki and J. Konings, 2014, “Importers, Exporters, and Exchange Rate Disconnect,” American Economic Review, 104(7), pp.1942~1978.
[11]Antràs, P., D. Chor, T. Fally and R. Hillberry, 2012, “Measuring the Upstreamness of Production and Trade Flows,” American Economic Review, 102(3), pp.412~416.
[12]Berman, N., P. Martin and T. Mayer, 2012, “How do Different Exporters React to Exchange Rate Changes?”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(1), pp.437~492.
[13]Chor, D., K. Manova and Z. Yu, 2021, “Growing like China: Firm Performance and Global Production Line Position,” Journal of International Economics, 130, p.103445.
[14]De Loecker, J. and F. Warzynski, 2012, “Markups and Firm-Level Export Status,” American Economic Review, 102(6), pp.2437~2471.
[15]Domowitz, I., R. G. Hubbard and B. C. Petersen, 1986, “Business Cycles and the Relationship between Concentration and Price-Cost Margins,” The RAND Journal of Economics, pp.1~17.
[16]García-Solanes, J. and F. Torrejón-Flores, 2010, “Devaluation and Pass-Through in Indebted and Risky Economies,” International Review of Economics & Finance, 19(1), pp.36~45.
[17]Goldberg, P. and M. M. Knetter, 1997, “Goods Prices and Exchange Rates: What Have We Learned?”, Journal of Economic Literature, 35(3), pp.1243~1272.
[18]Heckman, J. J., 1979, “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error,” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, pp.153~161.
[19]Ju, J. and X. Yu, 2015, “Productivity, Profitability, Production and Export Structures along the Value Chain in China,” Journal of Comparative Economics, 43(1), pp.33~54.
[20]Krugman, P. R., 1986, “Pricing to Market When the Exchange Rate Changes.”
[21]Li, H., H. Ma and Y. Xu, 2015, “How do Exchange Rate Movements Affect Chinese Exports?—A Firm-Level Investigation,” Journal of International Economics, 97(1), pp.148~161.
[22]Mallick, S. and H. Marques, 2012, “Pricing to Market with Trade Liberalization: The Role of Market Heterogeneity and Product Differentiation in India's Exports,” Journal of International Money and Finance, 31(2), pp.310~336.
[23]Mayer, T., M. J. Melitz and G. I. Ottaviano, 2014, “Market Size, Competition, and the Product Mix of Exporters,” American Economic Review, 104(2), pp.495~536.
[24]Miller, R. E. and U. Temurshoev, 2017, “Output Upstreamness and Input Downstreamness of Industries/Countries in World Production,” International Regional Science Review, 40(5), pp.443~475.
[25]Taylor, J. B., 2000, “Low Inflation, Pass-Through, and the Pricing Power of Firms,” European Economic Review, 44(7), pp.1389~1408.
[26]Wang, Z., S. J. Wei, X. Yu and K. Zhu, 2017, “Measures of Participation in Global Value Chains and Global Business Cycles,” National Bureau of Economic Research, No. w23222.
[1] 曾利飞, 蒋凯, 曹伟. 中国出口产品质量、汇率传递与出口定价能力 ——基于出口目的国收入分布视角[J]. 金融研究, 2023, 516(6): 75-93.
[2] 丁志杰, 谢峰. 汇率对中等收入国家经济跨越的影响研究[J]. 金融研究, 2017, 440(2): 42-53.
[3] 向训勇, 陈婷, 陈飞翔. 进口中间投入、企业生产率与人民币汇率传递——基于我国出口企业微观数据的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 435(9): 33-49.
[1] 韩珣, 李建军. 金融错配、非金融企业影子银行化与经济“脱实向虚”[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 482(8): 93 -111 .
[2] 梁若冰, 张东荣, 方心, 林细细. 限购政策是否降低了上市房地产企业价值?——基于强度双重差分法的经验研究[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 494(8): 42 -60 .
[3] 赵岩, 董小琦, 赵留彦. 银点套利与银跨境流动:中国银本位1902—1932[J]. 金融研究, 2023, 515(5): 189 -206 .
[4] 张楠, 刘蓉, 卢盛峰. 间接税亲贫性与代内归宿——穷人从减税中获益了吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 468(6): 76 -93 .
[5] 韩亚东, 杨丽梅, 邢春冰, 种聪. 社保降费如何影响企业用工结构?——基于正式用工与劳务外包选择视角的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2025, 541(7): 57 -75 .
[6] 孙波约, 于斌斌, 胡雅静. 算力基础设施建设是否抑制了企业“脱实向虚”?——来自中国地级及以上城市数据中心建设的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2025, 541(7): 95 -112 .
[7] 赵静梅, 何宝露. 企业声誉与违规行为——基于数字经济视角的新考证[J]. 金融研究, 2025, 541(7): 76 -94 .
[8] 邹伟, 鲁元平. 末端基础设施建设与农村包容性增长——兼论快递物流在全国统一大市场建设中的作用[J]. 金融研究, 2025, 541(7): 113 -130 .
[9] 徐细雄, 李万利. 儒家传统与企业创新:文化的力量[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 471(9): 112 -130 .
[10] 李伦一, 张翔. 中国房地产市场价格泡沫与空间传染效应[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 169 -186 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1