Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2022, Vol. 509 Issue (11): 1-20    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
通胀—增长权衡和中国菲利普斯曲线的平坦化
祝梓翔, 高然
四川大学经济学院, 四川成都 610065
The Inflation-Growth Trade-off and the Flattening of the Phillips Curve in China
ZHU Zixiang, GAO Ran
School of Economics, Sichuan University
下载:  PDF (1975KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 近年来发达经济体出现了菲利普斯曲线平坦化现象,但有关中国的研究尚缺乏共识。本文基于实证和理论分析,系统研究了中国菲利普斯曲线的平坦化问题。首先,结合货币政策冲击和月度SVAR框架,发现通胀的响应程度在2010年后大幅下降。由于证据显示总需求曲线并未平坦化,因此通胀响应弱化可解读为菲利普斯曲线的平坦化。数据显示,菲利普斯曲线平坦化与生产率增长放缓同时发生,因此,本文在标准DSGE模型中引入纵向内生增长渠道,该渠道基于研发投入和知识资本积累,从而使生产率内生于经济周期。研究发现:(1)内生增长渠道放大了需求冲击对产出的影响,但缩小了需求冲击对通胀的影响;(2)内生增长渠道改变通胀和增长之间的替代关系,但不改变边际成本向通胀的传导。分段估计显示,2010年后,通胀和增长的关系弱化是边际成本传导变弱和内生增长渠道变强共同作用的结果。本文认为,由于菲利普斯曲线的平坦化,中央银行应继续坚持稳增长和就业优先战略,关注但不必过于担心由此引发的通胀压力。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
祝梓翔
高然
关键词:  菲利普斯曲线  内生增长  货币政策  DSGE模型    
Summary:  Stabilizing growth has become a keyword in China's economy. Inflation and growth are the two primary macroeconomic objectives. According to classical macroeconomic theory, there is a trade-off between inflation and growth, at least in the short run, which is represented by the Phillips curve. The ability of central banks to control inflation depends on the strength of this trade-off. However, since the 1990s, there have been signs of a disconnect between inflation and growth in developed economies. One popular explanation for this disconnect is that the Phillips curves of these economies have flattened. This has led to an intense academic debate on whether and why the Phillips curves have flattened. Most studies show that the Phillips curves in developed economies have indeed flattened. However, a few economists disagree. Some studies explore whether China's Phillips curve has also flattened, with mixed results.
This study makes the following contributions.
First, most studies use partial equilibrium models to directly estimate various Phillips curves for China. However, this approach may suffer from varying degrees of misspecification and lack robustness. We indirectly analyze the trade-off between inflation and growth using demand shocks and a heteroskedastic monthly structural vector autoregressive model. The results show that inflation and output increase with a one-unit monetary policy shock. The inflation-relative response weakens substantially after 2010, with a significant decrease in the Phillips multiplier. In the robustness tests, the effect of economic policy uncertainty shocks on inflation likewise weakens substantially after 2010, and the primary findings hold in the factor model. Next, we exclude the possibility of a flat aggregate demand curve and find that the central bank's anti-inflationary awareness does not increase after 2010. Thus, the weakening inflation response can be interpreted as a flattening of the Phillips curve.
Second, considering that the period during which the Phillips curve flattens corresponds to a general slowdown in the Chinese economy, we argue that the two phenomena are compatible. We introduce knowledge capital accumulation and endogenous total factor productivity into the standard dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model. The results show that monetary policy and physical capital investment shocks are the main factors affecting inflation. The endogenous growth channel amplifies the effect of demand shocks on the output variables but weakens the effect on marginal costs and inflation. The endogenous growth channel negatively affects productivity, weakening the isokinetic relationship between inflation and output growth. The subsample estimation results show that the generalized Phillips curve flattens significantly after 2010 due to the combined effect of the endogenous growth channel and a weak marginal cost pass-through.
Our findings have broad implications for macroeconomic regulation and control in China. First, from a monetary policy perspective, the flattening of the Phillips curve eventually leads to a flattening of the aggregate supply curve, which implies that demand shocks play a prominent role and may dominate the economic cycle; therefore, it is beneficial for the central bank to take a Keynesian approach. If growth changes more than inflation, the central bank's objective function should empower growth and employment rather than strictly targeting inflation. A flat Phillips curve also implies a reduction in the central bank's ability to stabilize inflation, or a higher “sacrifice rate.” Ceteris paribus, greater changes in employment and output growth are needed to bring real inflation back on target. Second, from an endogenous growth perspective, more attention should be paid to “cross-cyclical adjustment.” To cope with the complex domestic and external economic environment, the government should make cross-cyclical adjustments and maintain policy continuity and stability. Due to the weakening relationship between inflation and output growth and the medium-to long-term nature of productivity evolution, policymakers should focus on the long-term dynamic equilibrium between growth stabilization and risk prevention, gradually moving away from smoothing out short-term fluctuations to providing medium-to long-term precautionary support. Third, from an inflationary perspective, although upside risks to global inflation remain, the central bank's Monetary Policy Implementation Report points out that China's inflation is largely manageable. Indeed, China's money supply has always matched its economic growth. Moreover, expanding the scope of demand-side policies may positively affect supply and productivity, thereby reducing the inflationary pressure on the economy.
Keywords:  Phillips Curve    Endogenous Growth    Monetary Policy    DSGE Model
JEL分类号:  E31   E32   E52  
基金资助: * 本文感谢国家自然科学基金青年项目(72003139)和中国博士后科学基金(2020M673196)资助。感谢匿名审稿人的宝贵意见,文责自负。
通讯作者:  高 然,经济学博士,副教授,四川大学经济学院,E-mail:gaoran@scu.edu.cn.   
作者简介:  祝梓翔,经济学博士,副教授,四川大学经济学院,E-mail:zhuzixiang@scu.edu.cn.
引用本文:    
祝梓翔, 高然. 通胀—增长权衡和中国菲利普斯曲线的平坦化[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 509(11): 1-20.
ZHU Zixiang, GAO Ran. The Inflation-Growth Trade-off and the Flattening of the Phillips Curve in China. Journal of Financial Research, 2022, 509(11): 1-20.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2022/V509/I11/1
[1] 白重恩和张琼,2015,《中国生产率估计及其波动分解》,《世界经济》第12期,第3~28页。
[2] 陈创练、郑挺国和姚树洁,2016,《时变参数泰勒规则及央行货币政策取向研究》,《经济研究》第8期,第43~56页。
[3] 陈创练、高锡蓉和刘晓彬,2022,《“稳增长”与“防风险”双目标的宏观调控政策抉择》,《金融研究》第1期,第19~37页。
[4] 陈汉鹏和卜振兴,2021,《中国通胀与产出的动态关系研究——基于状态空间模型的分析》,《当代经济管理》第5期,第7~13页。
[5] 何启志和姚梦雨,2017,《中国通胀预期测度及时变系数的菲利普斯曲线》,《管理世界》第5期,第66~78页。
[6] 刘哲希、郭俊杰、谭涵予和陈彦斌,2022,《货币政策能够兼顾“稳增长”与“稳杠杆”双重目标吗?--基于不同杠杆环境的比较》,《金融研究》第7期,第20~37页。
[7] 伍戈和刘琨,2014,《中国通胀与产出的动态研究——基于时变性的菲利普斯曲线》,《财贸经济》第10期,第61~72页。
[8] 祝梓翔和邓翔,2017,《时变视角下中国经济波动的再审视》,《世界经济》第7期,第3~27页。
[9] 张健华和王鹏,2012,《中国全要素生产率:基于分省份资本折旧率的再估计》,《管理世界》第10期,第18~30页。
[10] Bianchi, F., H. Kung, and G. Morales. 2019. “Growth, Slowdowns, and Recoveries”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 101: 47~63.
[11] Barnichon, R., and G. Mesters. 2021. “The Phillips Multiplier”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 117: 689~705.
[12] Baqaee, D., E. Farhi, and K. Sangani. 2022. “The Supply-side Effects of Monetary Policy”, NBER Working Paper, No. 28345.
[13] Chen, K., J. Ren, and T. Zha. 2018. “The Nexus of Monetary Policy and Shadow Banking in China”, American Economic Review, 108(12): 3891~3936.
[14] Chang, C., K. Chen, D. F. Waggoner, and T. Zha. 2016. “Trends and Cycles in China's Macroeconomy”, NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 30: 1~84.
[15] Chang, C., Z. Liu, M. M. Spiegel, and J. Zhang. 2019. “Reserve Requirements and Optimal Chinese Stabilization Policy”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 103: 33~51.
[16] Coibion, O., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2015. “Is the Phillips Curve Alive and Well After All? Inflation Expectations and The Missing Disinflation”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 7(1): 197~232.
[17] Del Negro, M., M. Lenza, G. E. Primiceri, and A. Tambalotti. 2020. “What's Up With The Phillips Curve?”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2020(1): 301~373.
[18] Del Negro, M., M. P. Giannoni, and F. Schorfheide. 2015. “Inflation in The Great Recession and New Keynesian Models”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 7(1): 168~196.
[19] Davis, S. J., D. Liu, and X. S. Sheng. 2019. “Economic Policy Uncertainty in China Since 1949: The View from Mainland Newspapers”, Working Paper.
[20] Justiniano, A., G. E., Primiceri, and A. Tambalotti. 2010. “Investment Shocks and Business Cycles”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 57(2): 132~145.
[21] Lenza, M., and G. E. Primiceri. 2022. “How to Estimate a VAR After March 2020”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 37(4): 688~699.
[22] McLeay, M., and S. Tenreyro. 2020. “Optimal Inflation and The Identification of The Phillips Curve”, in NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 34 (1), Eichenbaum, Hurst, and Parker.
[23] Mavroeidis, S., M. Plagborg-Møller, and J. H. Stock. 2014. “Empirical Evidence on Inflation Expectations in The New Keynesian Phillips Curve,” Journal of Economic Literature, 52(1): 124~188.
[24] Stock, J. H., and M. W. Watson. 2020. “Slack and Cyclically Sensitive Inflation”, Journal of Money, Credit And Banking, 52(S2): 393~428.
[1] 张成思, 唐火青, 陈贞竹. 货币政策冲击对实体企业投资选择影响的“宿醉效应”[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 507(9): 1-19.
[2] 吴迪, 张楚然, 侯成琪. 住房价格、金融稳定与宏观审慎政策[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 505(7): 57-75.
[3] 刘哲希, 郭俊杰, 谭涵予, 陈彦斌. 货币政策能够兼顾“稳增长”与“稳杠杆”双重目标吗?——基于不同杠杆环境的比较[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 505(7): 20-37.
[4] 郭杰, 饶含. 土地资产价格波动与经济中的流动性供给——基于以地融资视角的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 505(7): 76-93.
[5] 朱民, 彭道菊. 创新内含碳中和目标的结构性货币政策[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 504(6): 1-15.
[6] 王博, 陈开璞. 中国自然利率之谜与债券市场定价——基于宏观金融模型视角[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 504(6): 36-54.
[7] 刘建建, 王忏, 赵扶扬, 龚六堂. 住房耐用品、土地市场分割与货币失踪之谜[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 509(11): 21-39.
[8] 马勇, 吕琳. 货币、财政和宏观审慎政策的协调搭配研究[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 499(1): 1-18.
[9] 陈创练, 高锡蓉, 刘晓彬. “稳增长”与“防风险”双目标的宏观调控政策抉择[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 499(1): 19-37.
[10] 吴立元, 赵扶扬, 王忏, 龚六堂. 美国货币政策溢出效应、中国资产价格波动与资本账户管理[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 493(7): 77-94.
[11] 董兵兵, 徐慧伦, 谭小芬. 货币政策能够兼顾稳增长与防风险吗?——基于动态随机一般均衡模型的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 490(4): 19-37.
[12] 陆军, 黄嘉. 利率市场化改革与货币政策银行利率传导[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 490(4): 1-18.
[13] 战明华, 李帅, 姚耀军, 吴周恒. 投资潮涌、双重金融摩擦与货币政策传导——转型时期货币政策的结构调控功能探究[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 489(3): 1-17.
[14] 庄毓敏, 张祎. 流动性覆盖率监管会影响货币政策传导效率吗?——来自中国银行业的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 497(11): 1-21.
[15] 尚玉皇, 赵芮, 董青马. 混频数据信息下的时变货币政策传导行为研究——基于混频 TVP-FAVAR模型[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 487(1): 13-30.
[1] 张牧扬, 潘妍, 余泳泽. 社会信用、刚兑信仰与地方政府隐性债务[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 508(10): 1 -19 .
[2] 郭晔, 未钟琴, 方颖. 金融科技布局、银行信贷风险与经营绩效——来自商业银行与科技企业战略合作的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 508(10): 20 -38 .
[3] 潘敏, 刘红艳, 程子帅. 极端气候对商业银行风险承担的影响——来自中国地方性商业银行的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 508(10): 39 -57 .
[4] 邢秉昆. 碳减排约束下中国工业企业信用评级[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 509(11): 77 -97 .
[5] 刘建建, 王忏, 赵扶扬, 龚六堂. 住房耐用品、土地市场分割与货币失踪之谜[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 509(11): 21 -39 .
[6] 徐佳, 李冠华, 齐天翔. 中国家庭偿债能力:衡量与影响因素[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 509(11): 98 -116 .
[7] 李孟哲, 麻志明, 吴联生. 上市公司数量与非上市公司创新[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 509(11): 171 -188 .
[8] 朱永华, 张一林, 林毅夫. 赶超战略与大银行垄断——基于新结构经济学的视角[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 509(11): 40 -57 .
[9] 高翔, 张敏, 刘啟仁. 工业机器人应用促进了“两业融合”发展吗?——来自中国制造企业投入服务化的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 509(11): 58 -76 .
[10] 吴锟, 吴卫星, 王沈南. 金融教育是有效的吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 509(11): 117 -135 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1