School of Finance, Zhongnan University of Economics and Law; School of Finance, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics; FICC Department, Zhongtai Securities
Summary:
The capital market acts as a bridge to achieve market-based deleveraging through market-based approach and promote the optimization of the financing structures. Specifically, the capital market regulates the allocation of funds through its price discovery function, influencing the investment decisions of micro-individuals and leading to changes and adjustments in industrial structure. On the transmission chain of "price effect-resource allocation-micro investment-macro changes," external shocks lead to price changes in the stock market and bond market, which can generate economic externalities. However, there are currently few academic researches on whether overvaluation or undervaluation of bond market prices will produce the same capital change effects. A prominent feature of China's bond market is the expectation of rigid redemption for state-owned enterprise (SOE) bonds, which has led to the long-term overvaluation of many SOE bonds. Due to their greater financing advantages, some SOEs in high-pollution and high-energy-consumption industries tend to overinvest, resulting in overcapacity in the real economy and even the prevalence of "zombie enterprises." Obviously, the overvaluation of bond market prices exhibits negative externalities. However, does the capital market exist a negative transmission chain of "negative shock-price decline-capital outflow-industry contraction"? Cases such as the "Yongcheng Coal and Electricity Holding Group Co., Ltd. bond default" have shown that debt defaults of local state-owned enterprises can severely deteriorate the credit environment of local governments and related industries, with spillover effects causing significant difficulties in the issuance of corporate bonds in the same region and industry. Thus, it can be inferred that if the government reduces the level of implicit guarantees for SOE bonds, the decline in bond prices (and increase in financing costs) may push capital to flow out of inefficient enterprises, limit the funding supply to overcapacity enterprises, and provide a feasible path for clearing out backward capacity and optimizing industrial structure through market means. Does the aforementioned transmission mechanism exist in the capital market? Taking the policies implemented by the central and provincial (municipal) governments starting from the fourth quarter of 2015 to deal with enterprises with backward production capacity as an external shock, this paper uses a time-varying Difference-in-Differences (DID) method to compare the changes in bond financing, bank credit financing, leverage ratio, and other aspects between enterprises with outdated capacity and normal enterprises within state-owned enterprises. In this paper, we find that with the reduction in the level of implicit government guarantees by the implementation of the "cutting overcapacity, reducing excess inventory, deleveraging, lowering costs, and strengthening areas of weakness" policy, the bond prices of outdated production companies have fallen sharply. The bond issuance spread in the primary market has increased over 100 basis points on average, corresponding to a decline in bond prices by approximately 2.5%; among them, the issuance interest rates for long-term bonds have risen by over 160 basis points, corresponding to a decline in bond prices by more than 6%. The decline in bond prices has led to a significant reduction in the financing scale of bonds issued by enterprises with outdated production capacity, and the capital outflow effect on these enterprises is evident. However, the price contraction effect does not result in a decrease in the leverage ratio of enterprises with outdated production capacity, due to the refinancing support provided by other financing channels, which fills the gap in bond financing for these enterprises. Mechanism tests demonstrate that there is a relatively complete price discovery function in the bond secondary market, which can quickly respond to negative information and make adjustments. Moreover, the bond market exhibits distinct pro-cyclical characteristics in terms of capital allocation. It can fully reflect changes in the fundamentals and effectively mitigate financial risks and give full play to the pivotal role of the capital market. The policy recommendations of this paper are as follows: The bond market can optimize resource allocation through its price discovery function, achieving structural deleveraging and other supply-side reform goals while maintaining overall economic stability. Therefore, it is necessary to further leverage the pivotal role of capital markets, significantly increasing the proportion of direct financing in the macro-financial system and corporate micro-debt structure, enriching bond product offerings, and advancing the development of high-yield bond markets. It is also essential to gradually break the rigid redemption expectations for state-owned enterprise bonds, achieving market-based pricing for their issuance. Secondly,the construction of information disclosure and risk disclosure systems in the bond market should be further strengthened. The quality of information disclosure by bond-issuing enterprises should be improved to reduce information asymmetry, laying a solid foundation for the effective functioning of the bond market's regulatory mechanisms. Finally, to enhance the effectiveness of various fund placements, it is crucial to strengthen policy expectation management, guiding micro entities to form stable and consistent expectations of macroeconomic control targets, thereby reducing economic uncertainty.
[1]陈彦斌、刘哲希和陈伟泽,2018,《经济增速放缓下的资产泡沫研究——基于含有高债务特征的动态一般均衡模型》,《经济研究》第10期,第16~32页。 [2]董丰和许志伟,2020,《刚性泡沫:基于金融风险与刚性兑付的动态一般均衡分析》,《经济研究》第10期,第72~88页。 [3]冯玲、文璐和肖阳,2020,《基于政府隐性担保退出预期的金融机构违约风险重定价》,《中国管理科学》第11期,第43~50页。 [4]韩鹏飞和胡奕明,2015,《政府隐性担保定能降低债券的融资成本吗——关于国有企业和地方融资平台债券的实证研究》,《金融研究》第3期,第116~130页。 [5]李旭超和宋敏,2021,《僵尸企业债务支付拖欠与民营企业全要素生产率》,《世界经济》第11期,第49~74页。 [6]陆蓉、何婧和崔晓蕾,2017,《资本市场错误定价与产业结构调整》,《经济研究》第11期,第104~118页。 [7]王博森、吕元稹和叶永新,2016,《政府隐性担保风险定价:基于我国债券交易市场的探讨》,《经济研究》第10期,第155~167页。 [8]王万珺和刘小玄,2018,《为什么僵尸企业能够长期生存》,《中国工业经济》第10期,第63~81页。 [9]王永钦、陈映辉和杜巨澜,2016,《软预算约束与中国地方政府债务违约风险:来自金融市场的证据》,《经济研究》第11期,第96~109页。 [10]王宇伟、盛天翔和周耿,2018,《宏观政策, 金融资源配置与企业部门高杠杆率》,《金融研究》第1期,第36~52页。 [11]吴翌琳、张旻和于鸿君,2024,《融资方式与企业二元创新路径选择——基于技术创新与非技术创新视角》,《金融研究》第1期,第38~55页. [12]张斌,2020,《发达经济体为什么采取宽松货币政策》,《经济学动态》第12期,第28~39页。 [13]张一林和蒲明,2018,《债务展期与结构性去杠杆》,《经济研究》第7期,第32~46页。 [14]Caballero, R. J., T. Hoshi, T. and A. K. Kashyap, 2008, “Zombie Lending and Depressed Restructuring in Japan”, American Economic Review, 98(5), pp.1943~77. [15]Fisman, R. and J. Svensson, 2007, “Are Corruption and Taxation Really Harmful to Growth? Firm Level Evidence”, Journal of Development Economics, 83(1), pp.63~75. [16]Fukuda, S. I. and J. I. Nakamura, 2011, “Why Did ‘Zombie' Firms Recover in Japan?”, The World Economy, 34(7), pp.1124~1137. [17]Hoshi, T., 2006, “Economics of the Living Dead”, The Japanese Economic Review, 57(1), pp.30~49. [18]Titman, S., 2013, “Financial Markets and Investment Externalities”, The Journal of Finance. 68(4), pp.1307~1329.