Summary:
While studying the issue of trade and enterprise innovation, the existing literature treats enterprises with independent legal personality as a separate sample, ignoring the fact that a large number of business groups exist. In reality, there is often a great deal of non-market behavior amongst the subsidiaries of groups with independent legal personality, and through the strategic allocation of internal resources, business groups can maximize the interests of the group as a whole, rather than those of individual subsidiaries. Currently, some literature has investigated issues such as “hollowing out”, tax avoidance and pollution transfer within enterprise groups, but there is a lack of research focusing on the performance and coping strategies of business groups in the face of external shocks. Unlike non-group affiliates, enterprise groups have unique internal labor and capital markets and are able to allocate resources on a wider scale, and therefore may have better economic performance under external shocks. In order to clarify the above issues, in this paper, we investigate the differential impact of import competition on the innovation of firms with different organizational forms by using the large-scale tariff cuts after China's WTO accession as the quasi-natural experiment. Before starting the empirical study, we first provide a theoretical framework based on the theory of ‘organizational resilience’. We analyze in detail the path mechanism of business groups to cope with external shocks from three perspectives: strategic adjustment in the internal market, cross-industry diversification, and organizational restructuring of the group. Afterwards, we conducted descriptive statistics using data on Chinese manufacturing firms and hand-arranged relational networks of enterprise groups, and carried out empirical tests using the DID strategy and the event study method. The research in this paper provides some interesting findings: (1) The number of group affiliates is only about 29% of the total number of firms in the market, but contributes most of the output, employment and exports. (2) Most of the innovation of Chinese firms is contributed by group-affiliated firms. Specifically, the number of patent applications by group-affiliated firms accounts for about 70 percent of market share, while non-affiliated firms account for only about 30 percent. (3) The impact of import competition on innovation performance varies according to the organizational form of the firm, showing a dampening effect on single firms and a promoting effect on group-affiliated firms. (4) The reason for the better innovation performance of group-affiliated firms under import competition is that enterprise groups not only make use of the internal market to strategically allocate resources among subsidiaries in the same industry and adjust the focus of R&D and innovation across industries, but also adjust their organizational structure to revitalize internal innovation resources by eliminating inferior firms. (5) Further studies show that there is a division of labor for innovation within the group. Specifically, import competition significantly promotes the deepening and expanding innovation of innovative group-affiliated firms, but only promotes the expanding innovation of non-innovative ones; compared with private business groups, import competition has a greater effect on the innovation promotion of state-owned business groups; and import competition increases the number of utility model and design patents filed by the group's subsidiaries, but at the same time inhibits the number of invention patents filed. This paper not only finds that the innovation risk of a single enterprise is higher, but also, reveals the reasons why enterprise groups have better innovation performance under external shocks, and identifies the potential risk of low-quality innovation of business groups, which provides new ideas for China to co-ordinate openness and safe, and high-quality development, as well as important policy insights for accelerating the development of new-quality productivity. Based on the conclusions of this paper, we put forward feasible policy recommendations: first, against the backdrop of the current turbulent international situation and intensifying uncertainty in the external environment, the importance of business groups in promoting the innovation-driven development strategy should be highly emphasized. It should support and develop high-quality enterprise groups with innovative capabilities, promote their investment and development in key national industries and fields, and cultivate new innovative growth points. Second, reduce the institutional costs and barriers for business groups to fulfil their innovation functions. Further simplify the system of talent flow and asset flow within the group, improve the allocation efficiency of talent and capital among firms, and smooth the circulation channels of innovation factors by formulating a unified system standard for the group. Third, further reduce the system costs within the SOE group by reducing the equity hierarchy, and improve its reaction speed in dealing with shocks. Fourthly, through the establishment of enterprise science and technology innovation awards and titles for experts and talents, incentivize firms to shift to an innovative development model that improves quality and preserves quantity, and the risk-resistant capacity of single firms will be improved by tilting the policies and taking the lead in setting up enterprise alliances.
魏浩, 封起扬帆. 进口竞争、创新风险与创新质量——基于单一企业和企业集团的再考察[J]. 金融研究, 2024, 533(11): 57-75.
WEI Hao, FENG Qiyangfan. Import Competition,Innovation Risk and Innovation Quality:A Re-examination Based on Single Firms and Business Groups. Journal of Financial Research, 2024, 533(11): 57-75.
[1]蔡卫星、倪骁然、赵盼和杨亭亭,2019,《企业集团对创新产出的影响:来自制造业上市公司的经验证据》,《中国工业经济》第1期,第137~155页。 [2]何欢浪、蔡琦晟和章韬,2021,《进口贸易自由化与中国企业创新——基于企业专利数量和质量的证据》,《经济学(季刊)》第2期,第597~616页。 [3]黎文靖和郑曼妮,2016,《实质性创新还是策略性创新?——宏观产业政策对微观企业创新的影响》,《经济研究》第4期,第60~73页。 [4]马弘、乔雪和徐嫄,2013,《中国制造业的就业创造与就业消失》,《经济研究》第12期,第68~80页。 [5]宋德勇、朱文博、王班班和丁海,2021,《企业集团内部是否存在“污染避难所”》,《中国工业经济》第10期,第156~174页。 [6]田巍和余淼杰,2014,《中间品贸易自由化和企业研发:基于中国数据的经验分析》,《世界经济》第6期,第90~112页。 [7]魏浩和巫俊,2018,《知识产权保护、进口贸易与创新型领军企业创新》,《金融研究》第9期,第91~106页。 [8]杨岚、张瑞涵和周亚虹,2023,《进口竞争与技术距离》,《经济学(季刊)》第4期,第1302~1318页。 [9]杨汝岱,2015,《中国制造业企业全要素生产率研究》,《经济研究》第2期,第61~74页。 [10]张维迎、周黎安和顾全林,2003,《经济转型中的企业退出机制——关于北京市中关村科技园区的一项经验研究》,《经济研究》第10期,第3~14+90页。 [11]周煊、程立茹和王皓,2012,《技术创新水平越高企业财务绩效越好吗?——基于16年中国制药上市公司专利申请数据的实证研究》,《金融研究》第8期,第166~179页。 [12]Almeida H., C. S. Kim and H. B. Kim, 2015, “Internal Capital Markets in Business Groups: Evidence from the Asian Financial Crisis”, Journal of Finance, 70(6), pp.2539~2586. [13]Amiti M. and J. Konings, 2007, “Trade Liberalization, Intermediate Inputs, and Productivity: Evidence from Indonesia”, American Economic Review, 97(5), pp.1611~1638. [14]Baysinger B. D., R. D. Kosnik and T. A. Turk, 1991, “Effects of Board and Ownership Structure on Corporate R&D Strategy”, Academy of Management Journal, 34(1), pp.205~214. [15]Belenzon S. and T. Berkovitz, 2010, “Innovation in Business Groups”, Management Science, 56(3), pp.519~535. [16]Belenzon S, H. Lee and A. Patacconi, 2023, “Managing Risk in Corporate Groups: Limited Liability, Asset Partitioning, And Risk Compartmentalization”, Strategic Management Journal, 44(12), pp.2888~2921. [17]Bena J. and H. Ortiz-Molina, 2013, “Pyramidal Ownership and The Creation of New Firms”, Journal of Financial Economics, 108(3), pp.798~821. [18]Bombardini M., O. C. Rendina and F. Trebbi, 2021, “Lobbying Behind the Frontier”, NBER Working Paper, No. W29120. [19]Brandt L., J. V. Biesebroeck and Y. Zhang, 2012, “Creative Accounting or Creative Destruction? Firm-Level Productivity Growth in Chinese Manufacturing”, Journal of Development Economics, 97(2), pp.339~351. [20]Brandt L., V. Biesebroeck and L. Wang, 2017, “WTO Accession and Performance of Chinese Manufacturing Firms”, American Economic Review, 107(9), pp.2784~2820. [21]Castellacci F., 2015, “Institutional Voids or Organizational Resilience? Business Groups, Innovation, And Market Development in Latin America”, World Development, 70, pp.43~58. [22]Chang S J., C. N. Chung and I. P. Mahmood, 2006, “When and How Does Business Group Affiliation Promote Firm Innovation? A Tale of Two Emerging Economies”, Organization Science, 17(5), pp.637~656. [23]Chen C. and C. Steinwender, 2021, “Import Competition, Heterogeneous Preferences of Managers, And Productivity”, Journal of International Economics, 133, pp.103533. [24]Chung C. N., 2006, “Beyond Guanxi: Network Contingencies in Taiwanese Business Groups”, Organization Studies, 27(4), pp.461~489. [25]Faccio M. and W. J. O’Brien, 2021, “Business Groups and Employment”, Management Science, 67(6), pp.3468~3491. [26]Fernandes A. M. and C. Paunov, 2013, “Does Trade Stimulate Product Quality Upgrading?” Canadian Journal of Economics, 46(4), pp.1232~1264. [27]Fisman R. and Y. Wang, 2010, “Trading Favors Within Chinese Business Groups”, American Economic Review, 100(2), pp.429~433. [28]Goldberg P. K., A. K. Khandelwal and N. Pavcnik, 2010, “Imported Intermediate Inputs and Domestic Product Growth: Evidence from India”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(4), pp.1727~1767. [29]Guillen M. F., 2000, “Business Groups in Emerging Economies: A Resource-Based View”, Academy of Management Journal, 43(3), pp.362~380. [30]He J., X. Mao, O. M. Rui and X. Zha. 2013, “Business Groups in China”, Journal of Corporate Finance, 22, pp.166~192. [31]Jiang G., C. M. C. Lee and H Yue, 2010, “Tunneling Through Intercorporate Loans: The China Experience”, Journal of Financial Economics, 98(1), pp.1~20. [32]Khanna T. and Y. Yafeh., 2007, “Business Groups in Emerging Markets: Paragons or Parasites?”, Journal of Economic Literature, 45(2), pp.331~372. [33]Levinsohn J. and A. Petrin, 2003, “Estimating Production Functions Using Inputs to Control for Unobservables”, Review of Economic Studies, 70(2), pp.317~341. [34]Liu Q, R. Lu, Y. Lu and T. A. Luong, 2021, “Import Competition and Firm Innovation: Evidence from Chinas”, Journal of Development Economic, 151, pp.102650. [35]Lu Y. and L. Yu, 2015, “Trade Liberalization and Markup Dispersion: Evidence from China's WTO Accession”, American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 7(4), pp.221~253. [36]Mahmood I. P. and W. Mitchell, 2004, “Two Faces: Effects of Business Groups on Innovation in Emerging Economies”, Management Science, 50(10), pp.1348~1365. [37]Marin D. and T. Verdier, 2014, “Corporate Hierarchies and International Trade: Theory and Evidence”, Journal of International Economics, 94(2), pp.295~310. [38]Manikandan K. S. and J. Ramachandran, 2015, “Beyond Institutional Voids: Business Groups, Incomplete Markets, And Organizational Form”, Strategic Management Journal, 36(4), pp.598~617. [39]Masulis R. W., P. K. Pham and J. Zein, 2011, “Family Business Groups Around the World: Financing Advantages, Control Motivations, And Organizational Choices”, Review of Financial Studies, 24(11), pp.3556~3600. [40]Nolan P., 2001, China and The Global Economy: National Champions, Industrial Policy and The Big Business Revolution. Berlin: Springer Press.