Summary:
At present, the monetary policy cycle of major developed countries in Europe and the United States is frequently changed, which constitutes an external currency shock on the emerging economies with limited room for policy maneuver. The negative impact of external monetary shocks on domestic financial stability has attracted increasing attention, although the academic community has theoretically discussed the spillover effect of central countries' monetary policies on other economies and the significance of developing countries' proactive policies to offset external shocks and maintain financial stability. However, due to the endogeneity of money supply under the credit standard, it is difficult to accurately answer this question from the angle of causal identification. Nevertheless, China in the 1930s provided us with a rare opportunity to observe and answer this question at the institutional level. By collecting the information on customs imports, city prices, bank finance and so on in modern China, this paper studies the causal effect of external monetary shock on financial stability by using the impact of the US Silver Act of 1934, and analyzes the role of China's free banking system in coping with the crisis. In the early 1930s, China was the only major country in the world that used the silver standard system, and its silver stock and total money supply were controlled by the balance of payments and the international silver price. At the same time, China had no substantive central bank, forming a banking system that resembled a "free banking system." As the previous silver price downturn hurt the interests of the seven silver producing states in the United States, under the promotion of these silver interest groups, the Roosevelt government promulgated the Silver Act in June 1934, authorizing the Treasury Department to buy silver from the international market at a high price, resulting in an increase of 70 percent in the international silver price in less than a year. The Silver Act had a significant impact on China under the silver standard, including a large outflow of silver and deflation. However, scholars, including Milton Friedman and Thomas Sargent, held opposing views on the actual impact of the Silver Act and the role of the free banking system. Contrary to the monetarist view, economists such as Sargent argued that China's deflation at the time was only the result of international arbitrage, and China's real economy was not greatly affected. In order to re-examine the impact of the Silver Act, an exogenous monetary tightening shock, on China's financial economy in modern times from a micro perspective, we manually collected and sorted out the available data of China's urban prices, customs imports, bank finance, real economy, etc. These data come from the statistics of the Chinese old customs, the National Bank Yearbook compiled by the Bank of China, the industrial survey of the Nanking National Government and other authoritative archival materials at that time. We construct an index to measure the shock intensity of the Silver Act based on China's silver standard monetary system and commercial banks' currency issuance system .Through the exogenous shock of the Silver Act and the analysis of the price indices of major Chinese cities, we find that, in addition to controlling the impact of international price arbitrage, the monetary tightening has led to a significant decline in prices and deflation, as well as a shortage of liquidity in the interbank market. Concerned about tight market liquidity and rising risks, banks have reduced the size of their loans and reduced their support for the real economy. This means that the monetary tightening shock has a negative impact on the stability of the financial system and macro liquidity. In addition to the direct impact on the financial system, the Silver Act also had a significant negative impact on the real economy. Under the tightening shock, the number of new enterprises and the area of real estate construction have declined significantly, suggesting that external monetary shocks not only affect the price level, but also have significant actual effects. At the same time, the analysis of the free banking system shows that the free banking system under the absence of the central bank cannot resolve the negative impact of external currency shocks in time. This also means that it is important to ensure the flexibility of the monetary policy of the central bank to cope with the impact of external monetary shocks.
[1]陈雨露、马勇和阮卓阳,2016,《金融周期和金融波动如何影响经济增长与金融稳定?》,《金融研究》第2期,第1~22页。 [2]城山智子,2010,《大萧条时期的中国》,江苏人民出版社2010年第一版。 [3]董昕,2014,《近代中国银行业领券发行制度的演进》,《中国经济史研究》第1期,第100~114页。 [4]杜恂诚,2019,《中国的民族资本主义(1927-1937)》,上海财经大学出版社2019年6月第一版。 [5]管汉晖,2007,《20世纪30年代大萧条中的中国宏观经济》,《经济研究》第2期,第16~26页。 [6]关永强和伍韵琛,2020,《近代中国物价指数考略》,《中国经济史研究》第4期,第162~171页。 [7]纪敏、严宝玉和李宏瑾,2017,《杠杆率结构、水平和金融稳定——理论分析框架和中国经验》,《金融研究》第2期,第11~25页。 [8]蒋清宏,2015,《近代中国白银通货存量与货币供给总量考论——与罗斯基教授商榷》,《中国经济史研究》第3期,第108~116页。 [9]李斌和吴恒宇,2019,《对货币政策和宏观审慎政策双支柱调控框架内在逻辑的思考》,《金融研究》第12期, 第1~17页。 [10]李妍,2009,《宏观审慎监管与金融稳定》,《金融研究》第8期,第52~60页。 [11]刘冲和盘宇章,2013,《银行间市场与金融稳定——理论与证据》,《金融研究》第12期,第72~86页。 [12]马骏和何晓贝,2019,《货币政策与宏观审慎政策的协调》,《金融研究》第12期,第 58~69页。 [13]马勇、田拓和阮卓阳,2016,《金融杠杆、经济增长与金融稳定》,《金融研究》第6期,第37~51页。 [14]马勇、张靖岚和陈雨露,2017,《金融周期与货币政策》,《金融研究》第3期,第33~53页。 [15]沈雷春,1939,《中国金融年鉴》,文海出版社1939年版。 [16]燕红忠,2020,《中国金融史》,上海财经大学出版社2020年9月第一版。 [17]赵留彦和隋福民,2011,《美国白银政策与大萧条时期的中国经济》,《中国经济史研究》第4期,第31~43页。 [18]郑成林,2004,《上海银行公会与银行法制建设述评(1927-1936)》,《华中师范大学学报(人文社会科学版)》第4期,第15~23页。 [19]中国宏观经济形势分析与展望课题组,2022,《外部冲击频发期的宏观经济政策空间》,《经济学动态》第5期,第3~14页。 [20]Ahlquist, J., Copelovitch, M., and Walter, S. ,2020. “The Political Consequences of External Economic Shocks: Evidence From Poland”, American Journal of Political Science, 64(4),pp.904~920. [21]Allen F, and Gale D.,2000. “Financial Contagion”, Journal of Political Economy, 108(1) ,pp. 1~33. [22]Allen F, Gale D.,2004. “Financial Intermediaries and Markets”, Econometrica, 72(4) ,pp.1023~1061. [23]Aoki K, Benigno G, and Kiyotaki N. ,2016.“Monetary and Financial Policies in Emerging Markets”, Unpublished paper, London School of Economics. [24]Bernanke B.,1983. “Non-monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression”, NBER Working Paper,No.1054. [25]Bouis, R., Rawdanowicz, Ł., Renne, J. P., Watanabe, S., & Christensen, A. K.,2013. The Effectiveness of Monetary Policy Since the Onset of the Financial Crisis. [26]Braggion, F., Manconi, A., and Zhu, H. ,2020. “Credit and Social Unrest: Evidence From 1930s China”, Journal of Financial Economics, 138(2),pp.295~315. [27]Brandt, L., and Sargent, T. J.,1989. “Interpreting New Evidence About China and US Silver Purchases”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 23(1),pp.31~51. [28]Curdia V and Woodford M.,2011. “The Central-bank Balance Sheet as an Instrument of Monetary Policy”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 58(1),pp.54~79. [29]Fisher I.,1933. “The Debt-deflation Theory of Great Depressions”,Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society,pp.337~357. [30]Friedman, M., and Schwartz, A. J.,1963. A monetary History of the United States,1867-1960(Vol. 16). Princeton University Press. [31]Friedman, M.,1992. “Franklin D. Roosevelt, Silver, and China”, Journal of Political Economy, 100(1),pp.62~83. [32]Gertler M and Hubbard R G,1988. “Financial Factors in Business Fluctuations”, NBER Working Paper,No.2758. [33]Kaminsky G L and Reinhart C M.,1999. “The Twin Crises: the Causes of Banking and Balance-of-payments Problems”, American Economic Review, 89(3),pp.473~500. [34]Keynes, J. M.,1937. “The General Theory of Employment”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 51(2),pp.209~223. [35]Minsky H P.,1986. “The Evolution of Financial Institutions and the Performance of the Economy”, Journal of Economic Issues,, 20(2),pp.345~353. [36]Miranda-Agrippino S and Rey H.,2020. “US Monetary Policy and the Global Financial Cycle”, The Review of Economic Studies, 87(6),pp.2754~2776. [37]Obstfeld, M.,2014. “On the Use of Open Economy New Keynesian Models to Evaluate Policy Rules”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 49,pp.31~34. [38]Obstfeld M, Ostry J D and Qureshi M S.,2019. “A Tie That Binds: Revisiting the Trilemma in Emerging Market Economies”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 101(2),pp. 279~293. [39]Fraccaroli, N., and Pizzigolotto, A., 2021. Credit Shocks and Populism. [40]Rawski, T.,1984, “Estimates of China's Money Supply, 1910-1936,” Unpublished paper. [41]Rey H.,2015, “Dilemma Not Trilemma: the Global Financial Cycle and Monetary Policy Independence,” NBER Working Paper,No.21162. [42]Schwartz, A. J., 1998, “Why Financial Stability Depends on Price Stability,”Money, Prices and the Real Economy(Vol. 34, p. 41). Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar. [43]Woodford M,2012, “Inflation Targeting and Financial Stability,” NBER Working Paper,No.17967. [44]Yeh, K. C.,1964. Capital Formation in Mainland China: 1931-1936 and 1952-1957(Doctoral dissertation, Columbia University.