Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2022, Vol. 505 Issue (7): 57-75    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
住房价格、金融稳定与宏观审慎政策
吴迪, 张楚然, 侯成琪
武汉大学经济与管理学院,湖北武汉 430072;
华夏银行昆明分行,云南昆明 650021;
北京理工大学人文与社会科学学院,北京 100081
House Prices,Financial Stability and Macro-prudential Policies
WU Di, ZHANG Churan, HOU Chengqi
School of Economics and Management, Wuhan University;
Kunming Branch, Huaxia Bank;
School of Humanities and Social Sciences, Beijing Institute of Technology
下载:  PDF (1456KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 本文通过建立包含异质性家庭、异质性厂商和金融机构的DSGE模型,分析对预期房价作出反应的货币政策和宏观审慎政策的传导机制和政策效果,研究不同政策的选择和协调问题。研究发现,首先,由于政策的作用范围不同,不同政策会对金融稳定和经济稳定产生不同影响。对预期房价作出反应的货币政策能够抑制住房需求和信贷供给,但也会抑制消费需求和产出;而对预期房价作出反应的逆周期LTV政策和逆周期资本充足率政策在应对房价波动导致的金融稳定问题时更加有的放矢。其次,外生冲击的来源会影响政策的选择和协调——当经济波动来源于需求冲击时,固定LTV政策搭配逆周期资本充足率的宏观审慎政策、不对预期房价作出反应的货币政策表现最优;当经济波动来源于供给冲击时,固定LTV政策搭配逆周期资本充足率的宏观审慎政策、对预期房价作出反应的货币政策表现最优。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
吴迪
张楚然
侯成琪
关键词:  住房价格  金融稳定  经济稳定  宏观审慎政策  货币政策    
Summary:  In recent years, house prices and real estate loans in China have risen sharply, and the volatility of real estate loans in China is mainly driven by the volatility of residential mortgages. Studying how the macro-prudential policy aimed at enhancing the stability of the whole financial system should deal with the rise of house prices and the related debt risk is of great significance for China to prevent and resolve major financial risks. Existing research does not consider the choice of and coordination issues between monetary policy with financial stability as the second goal and the macro-prudential policy to address house price fluctuations and related debt risk. To fill this gap, this article incorporates the monetary policy, macro-prudential policy targeting household sector loan-to-value (LTV) and macro-prudential policy targeting the capital adequacy of financial institutions in a unified analysis framework, analyzes the transmission mechanisms and policy effects of these three policies, and studies policy choice and coordination issues.
First, this article constructs a DSGE model containing heterogeneous households, heterogeneous vendors and financial institutions. The theoretical analysis shows that for patient households, only the monetary policy responding to expected house prices can directly curb their housing demand. For impatient households and financial institutions, both the monetary policy responding to expected house prices and the macro-prudential policy responding to expected house prices can curb the rise of house prices and credit expansion. Different policies have different scopes and different effects on financial stability and economic stability. A monetary policy responding to expected house prices can curb not only housing demand and credit supply but also consumer demand and aggregate output, while a counter-cyclical LTV policy and a counter-cyclical capital adequacy policy responding to expected house prices are more targeted in dealing with the financial stability issues arising from house price volatility.
Second, based on the quarterly macroeconomic data of China from 2000 to 2021, this article adopts a Bayesian approach to select the economic model with the best fitness. The results show that the policy portfolio of the economic model with the best fitness is a monetary policy responding to expected house prices combined with a macro-prudential policy of counter-cyclical LTV. The variance decomposition shows that the volatility of the main macroeconomic variables, such as aggregate output, aggregate consumption, aggregate investment and inflation, is mainly affected by monetary policy shock, while the volatility of the main macro-financial variables, such as loan size, household sector LTV, financial institution leverage ratio and macro leverage ratio, are mainly affected by shocks from house transaction cost, financial institution regulatory and household sector LTV. In addition, shocks from house transaction costs and monetary policy explain more than 95% of house price fluctuations.
Finally, this article explores the issue of policy choice and coordination using impulse-response analysis and welfare analysis. The impulse-response analysis reveals that a counter-cyclical LTV policy and a counter-cyclical capital adequacy policy are more effective in responding to expected house prices when facing a house transaction cost shock, while a monetary policy responding to expected house prices may hurt economic stability. Given a monetary policy shock, a monetary policy responding to expected house prices is more effective than a macro-prudential policy responding to expected house prices. In sum, both macro-prudential policies and a monetary policy that respond to expected house prices contribute to financial stability. The result of the welfare analysis suggests that when economic fluctuations originate from demand shocks, a fixed LTV policy combined with counter-cyclical capital adequacy policy and a monetary policy not responding to expected house prices perform best, while a fixed LTV policy combined with counter-cyclical capital adequacy and a monetary policy responding to expected house prices perform best during economic fluctuations that originate from supply shocks.
Our research has important policy implications for China's macroeconomic regulation. First, the regulation principle of houses being for living in and not for speculation should be strictly implemented to highlight the attributes of housing as a consumer good and weaken its attributes as an investment good. Second, it is necessary to analyze the transmission mechanism and policy effect of different macroeconomic policies, such as macro-prudential policies of counter-cyclical LTV and counter-cyclical capital adequacy and a monetary policy responding to expected house prices, and to strengthen the coordination and cooperation between various policies. Finally, to prevent and resolve major financial risks, it is necessary to accurately identify the sources of economic volatility and optimally combine different policies according to their characteristics and the sources of economic volatility.
Keywords:  House Price    Financial Stability    Economic Stability    Macro-prudential Policy    Monetary Policy
JEL分类号:  E44   E52   E61  
基金资助: * 本文感谢国家自然科学基金项目“时间维度的宏观审慎政策:传导机制、政策规则与政策协调”(72073104)和国家社会科学基金重大项目“货币政策分配效应与缩小收入和财富差距的有效路径研究”(20&ZD105)的资助。感谢匿名审稿人的宝贵意见,文责自负。
通讯作者:  侯成琪,管理学博士,教授,北京理工大学人文与社会科学学院,E-mail: cqhou@bit.edu.cn.   
作者简介:  吴 迪,经济学博士,武汉大学经济与管理学院,E-mail: 2018101050042@whu.edu.cn.
张楚然,经济学硕士,华夏银行昆明分行,E-mail: churanzhang@whu.edu.cn.
引用本文:    
吴迪, 张楚然, 侯成琪. 住房价格、金融稳定与宏观审慎政策[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 505(7): 57-75.
WU Di, ZHANG Churan, HOU Chengqi. House Prices,Financial Stability and Macro-prudential Policies. Journal of Financial Research, 2022, 505(7): 57-75.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2022/V505/I7/57
[1] 程方楠和孟卫东,2017,《宏观审慎政策与货币政策的协调搭配——基于贝叶斯估计的 DSGE 模型》,《中国管理科学》第1期, 第11~20页。
[2] 陈彦斌和邱哲圣,2011,《高房价如何影响居民储蓄率和财产不平等》,《经济研究》第10期, 第25~38页。
[3] 侯成琪和龚六堂,2014,《货币政策应该对住房价格波动作出反应吗——基于两部门动态随机一般均衡模型的分析》,《金融研究》第10期,第15~33页。
[4] 况伟大和王琪琳,2017,《房价波动、 房贷规模与银行资本充足率》,《金融研究》第11期,第34~48页。
[5] 莱因哈特和罗格夫,2017,《这次不一样:八百年金融危机史》,机械工业出版社。
[6] 李波和朱太辉,2020,《债务杠杆、金融素养与家庭金融脆弱性——基于中国家庭追踪调查CFPS2014的实证分析》,《国际金融研究》第7期,第25~34页。
[7] 潘敏和周闯,2019,《宏观审慎监管、 房地产市场调控和金融稳定——基于贷款价值比的 DSGE 模型分析》,《国际金融研究》第4期,第14~23页。
[8] 阮健弘、刘西和叶欢,2020,《我国居民杠杆率现状及影响因素研究》,《金融研究》第8期,第18~33页。
[9] 司登奎、葛新宇和曾涛等,2019,《房价波动、 金融稳定与最优宏观审慎政策》,《金融研究》第11期,第38~56页。
[10] 谭政勋和王聪,2015,《房价波动、货币政策立场识别及其反应研究》,《经济研究》第1期,第67~83页。
[11] 王频和侯成琪,2017,《预期冲击、 房价波动与经济波动》,《经济研究》第4期,第 48~63页。
[12] 王云清、朱启贵和谈正达,2013,《中国房地产市场波动研究——基于贝叶斯估计的两部门DSGE模型》,《金融研究》第3期,第101~113页。
[13] 肖争艳和彭博,2011,《住房价格与中国货币政策规则》,《统计研究》第11期,第40~49页。
[14] 张李登、唐齐鸣和张誉航,2019,《房价波动、 住房信贷与宏观审慎政策》,《中国管理科学》第6期,第1~9页。
[15] 周广肃和王雅琦,2019,《住房价格、 房屋购买与中国家庭杠杆率》,《金融研究》第6期,第1~19页。
[16] Allahrakha, M., J. Cetina and B. Munyan,2018, “Do Higher Capital Standards Always Reduce Bank Risk? The impact of the Basel leverage ratio on the US triparty repo market,” Journal of Financial Intermediation, 34, pp.3~16.
[17] Barsky, R., C. L. House and M. Kimball,2007,“Sticky Price Models and Durable Goods,” Macroeconomics, 97(3), pp.984~998.
[18] Blum, J. M., 2008, “Why ‘Basel II' May Need a Leverage Ratio Restriction,”Journal of Banking and Finance, 32(8), pp.1699~1707.
[19] Christiano, L. J., M. Eichenbaum and C. L. Evans, 2005,“Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy,”Journal of political Economy,113(1), pp.1~45.
[20] Finocchiaro, D.and V. Q.Von Heideken, 2013,“Do Central Banks React to House price?” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 45, pp.1659~83.
[21] Freixas, X., L. Laeven and J. L.Peydró, 2015,“Systemic Risk, Crises, and Macroprudential Regulation,”MIT Press.
[22] Galati, G. and R. Moessner, 2018, “What do We Know about the Effects of Macroprudential Policy”, Economica, 85(340), pp.735~770.
[23] Gertler, M. and P. Karadi, 2011,“A Model of Unconventional Monetary Policy,”Journal of monetary Economics, 58(1), pp.17~34.
[24] Gorton, G. and G. Ordoñez,2020,“Good Booms, Bad Booms,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 18(2),pp.618~665.
[25] Guerrieri, L. and M. Iacoviello,2017,“Collateral Constraints and Macroeconomic Asymmetries,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 90,pp. 28~49.
[26] Horvath, M.,2000,“Sectoral Shocks and Aggregate Fluctuations,”Journal of Monetary Economics, 45(1), pp.69~106.
[27] Iacoviello, M., 2005,“House Price, Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle,” American Economic Review, 95(3), pp.739~764.
[28] Jensen, H., S. H. Ravn and E. Santoro, 2018,“Changing Credit Limits, Changing Business Cycles,” European Economic Review, 102, pp.211~239.
[29] Jordà, Ò., M. Schularick and A. M. Taylor, 2013, “When Credit Bites Back,”Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 45(s2), pp. 3~28.
[30] Jordà, Ò., M. Schularick and A. M. Taylor. 2015a,“Betting the House,”Journal of International Economics, 96, pp.S2~S18.
[31] Jordà, Ò., M. Schularick and A. M. Taylor, 2015b,“Leveraged Bubbles,”Journal of Monetary Economics, 76, pp. S1~S20.
[32] Kiema, I. and E. Jokivuolle, 2014,“Does a Leverage Ratio Requirement Increase Bank Stability?” Journal of Banking and Finance, 39, pp.240~254.
[33] Kuttner, K. N. and I. Shim, 2016, “Can Non-interest Rate Policies Stabilize Housing Markets? Evidence from a panel of 57 economies,” Journal of Financial Stability, 26, pp.31~44.
[34] Mian, A., A. Sufi and E. Verner, 2017, “Household Debt and Business Cycles Worldwide,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 132(4), pp.1755~1817.
[35] Mirza, A. and F. Strobel, 2013,“On the Use of Leverage Caps in Bank Regulation,”Working Paper.
[36] Nabar, M. S. and A. Ahuja, 2011, “Safeguarding Banks and Containing Property Booms: Cross-country Evidence on Macroprudential Policies and Lessons from Hong Kong SAR,” Imf Working Papers, 11(284).
[37] Notarpietro, A. and S. Siviero, 2015, “Optimal Monetary Policy Rules and House Price: the Role of Financial Frictions.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 47(S1), pp.383~410.
[38] Richter, B., M. Schularick and P. Wachtel, 2021,“When to Lean Against the Wind,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 53(1), pp.5~39.
[39] Smith, A. J., M. Grill and J. H. Lang,2018,“The Leverage Ratio, Risk-taking and Bank Stability,” Working Paper.
[40] Zhang, L. and E. Zoli, 2016, “Leaning Against the Wind: Macroprudential Policy in Asia,” Journal of Asian Economics, 42, pp.33~52.
[1] 郭杰, 饶含. 土地资产价格波动与经济中的流动性供给——基于以地融资视角的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 505(7): 76-93.
[2] 刘哲希, 郭俊杰, 谭涵予, 陈彦斌. 货币政策能够兼顾“稳增长”与“稳杠杆”双重目标吗?——基于不同杠杆环境的比较[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 505(7): 20-37.
[3] 朱民, 彭道菊. 创新内含碳中和目标的结构性货币政策[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 504(6): 1-15.
[4] 王博, 陈开璞. 中国自然利率之谜与债券市场定价——基于宏观金融模型视角[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 504(6): 36-54.
[5] 陈创练, 高锡蓉, 刘晓彬. “稳增长”与“防风险”双目标的宏观调控政策抉择[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 499(1): 19-37.
[6] 马勇, 吕琳. 货币、财政和宏观审慎政策的协调搭配研究[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 499(1): 1-18.
[7] 吴立元, 赵扶扬, 王忏, 龚六堂. 美国货币政策溢出效应、中国资产价格波动与资本账户管理[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 493(7): 77-94.
[8] 董兵兵, 徐慧伦, 谭小芬. 货币政策能够兼顾稳增长与防风险吗?——基于动态随机一般均衡模型的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 490(4): 19-37.
[9] 陆军, 黄嘉. 利率市场化改革与货币政策银行利率传导[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 490(4): 1-18.
[10] 钱宗鑫, 王芳, 孙挺. 金融周期对房地产价格的影响——基于SV-TVP-VAR模型的实证研究[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 489(3): 58-76.
[11] 战明华, 李帅, 姚耀军, 吴周恒. 投资潮涌、双重金融摩擦与货币政策传导——转型时期货币政策的结构调控功能探究[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 489(3): 1-17.
[12] 庄毓敏, 张祎. 流动性覆盖率监管会影响货币政策传导效率吗?——来自中国银行业的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 497(11): 1-21.
[13] 尚玉皇, 赵芮, 董青马. 混频数据信息下的时变货币政策传导行为研究——基于混频 TVP-FAVAR模型[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 487(1): 13-30.
[14] 侯成琪, 黄彤彤. 流动性、银行间市场摩擦与借贷便利类货币政策工具[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 483(9): 78-96.
[15] 庄子罐, 贾红静, 刘鼎铭. 居民风险偏好与中国货币政策的宏观经济效应——基于DSGE模型的数量分析[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 483(9): 40-58.
[1] 何青, 钱宗鑫, 刘伟. 中国系统性金融风险的度量——基于实体经济的视角[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 454(4): 53 -70 .
[2] 陈斌开, 张淑娟, 申广军. 义务教育能提高代际流动性吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 492(6): 76 -94 .
[3] 孙天阳, 成丽红. 协同创新网络与企业出口绩效——基于社会网络和企业异质性的研究[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 477(3): 96 -114 .
[4] 王姝勋, 董艳. 期权激励与企业并购行为[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 477(3): 169 -188 .
[5] 方意, 邵稚权. 中国金融周期与横向关联:时空双维度相结合视角[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 499(1): 38 -56 .
[6] 明雷, 秦晓雨, 杨胜刚. 差别化存款保险费率与银行风险承担——基于我国农村银行的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 501(3): 41 -59 .
[7] 朱民, 彭道菊. 创新内含碳中和目标的结构性货币政策[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 504(6): 1 -15 .
[8] 尚玉皇, 李炜祺, 董青马. 公开市场操作与利率期限结构行为——基于混频数据信息的研究视角[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 504(6): 16 -35 .
[9] 王博, 陈开璞. 中国自然利率之谜与债券市场定价——基于宏观金融模型视角[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 504(6): 36 -54 .
[10] 中国人民银行数字货币研究所课题组. 泰达币(USDT)与人民币汇率相关性研究[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 504(6): 55 -73 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1