Please wait a minute...
金融研究  2022, Vol. 501 Issue (3): 1-19    
  本期目录 | 过刊浏览 | 高级检索 |
贸易成本与中国制造
郭凯明, 陈昊, 颜色
中山大学岭南学院,广东广州 510275;
北京大学光华管理学院,北京 100871
Trade Cost and “Made in China”
GUO Kaiming, CHEN Hao, YAN Se
Lingnan College, Sun Yat-sen University;
Guanghua School of Management, Peking University
下载:  PDF (2046KB) 
输出:  BibTeX | EndNote (RIS)      
摘要 制造业是立国之本、强国之基,是大国经济的压舱石,更高水平、更有竞争力的制造业是高质量发展的基础。改革开放后中国制造业发展既受益于推动对外开放和融入全球贸易体系,也深刻影响了世界分工格局和外国福利水平。本文结合长期收入效应、投资结构变迁、国际贸易失衡等中国经济特征建立了一个两国多部门结构转型模型,从理论和定量上研究了贸易成本对中国制造业发展和外国福利提升的影响。本文发现:1995-2010年中国出口贸易成本持续下降,既增强了中国制造产品的比较优势,使制造业产出增长了29%,分别提高了制造业就业比重和产出比重4.7个和5.1个百分点;也由此降低了全球消费品价格,对同期外国总体福利水平提升的贡献率接近15%。对中国制造产品加征关税提高中国出口贸易成本,会显著降低外国福利水平。本文结论表明,中国是经济全球化的受益者,更是贡献者。本文为全面提高对外开放水平构建新发展格局提供了现实依据,并为加快建设制造强国、推动高质量发展提供参考。
服务
把本文推荐给朋友
加入引用管理器
E-mail Alert
RSS
作者相关文章
郭凯明
陈昊
颜色
关键词:  中国制造  结构转型  国际贸易  制造业    
Summary:  Manufacturing is the foundation of developing countries and provides support to major economies. It plays a key role in a country becoming rich and powerful. High-standard and more competitive manufacturing is a basic requirement for high-quality development. China's economic development is undergoing a rapid transition that requires manufacturing to build a modern socialist China and to develop the real economy. The government sees high-quality manufacturing as one of the most important drivers of high-quality development. China's manufacturing industry is growing rapidly and opening up constantly during the reform era. To what extent does China's high-standard opening-up affect its manufacturing development and global welfare? How should China continue to promote structural transformation during its reform and opening-up? Studies fail to answer these questions either theoretically or quantitatively from a macroeconomic perspective. This paper studies the macroeconomic effects of the cost of trade on China's manufacturing development and global welfare through theoretical analysis and quantitative experiments, which may offer novel answers to these questions.
We build a two-country multi-sector structural change model with complete input-output links, endogenous consumption and investment structure, and endogenous international trade shares. The model incorporates long-term income effects, structural changes in investment, and sectoral trade imbalance, which are the key features of China's economy. Theoretically, the fall in export trade costs decreases the price of China's manufacturing goods in the global market, which in turn increases their relative demand across the world, as well as the share of manufacturing in China's economy. It may also lower the average price of consumption goods sold to foreign people, which increases their purchasing power and welfare.
We apply the model to China's economy to account for the process of opening-up and manufacturing development. We find that the fall in the trade cost of Chinese exports from 1995 to 2010 enhances the comparative advantage of China's manufacturing, which in turn increases China's manufacturing output by 29% and thereby increases the employment and output share of manufacturing by 4.7 and 5.1 percentage points, respectively. It also accounts for nearly 15% of the growth of foreign welfare. Almost 80% of these effects emerged after 2001, when China joined the World Trade Organization. Moreover, imposing tariffs on Chinese goods to raise the trade cost of Chinese exports will not only hinder the development of China's manufacturing but also result in significant foreign welfare loss. If the trade cost of Chinese exports rises by 1 unit, manufacturing output will decline by 5.37 percent, with its employment share falling by 3.32 percentage points, and foreign welfare will also decrease by 0.89 percent.
Mounting protectionism, the dim prospects of the world economy, the shrinking global market, and the backlash against economic globalization have added to the risks and uncertainties in China's development. China should become a quality manufacturer to foster the new development dynamic.
We derive two policy implications from the findings of this paper. First, China should vigorously pursue admission to new regional trade agreements, advocate for new multilateral trading systems, and promote its manufacturing and market. Developing high-quality manufacturing in China may also help to build a higher-standard open economy and offer many opportunities for the world. China should also reinforce high-standard domestic and international circulations to enhance the competitiveness of its manufacturing across the globe. Policies such as encouraging international trade in producer services or building a pilot digital trade zone may promote technological innovation and structural updating of China's manufacturing industry. Second, China should further reform its factor market to improve factor allocation efficiency. This may lower the domestic cost of trade to form a unified national market and domestic circulation, which will in turn enhance the resilience of China's supply chain. China should also promote timely investment in new types of manufacturing, secure the production and supply of energy, and effectively tackle the problem of rising costs of manufacturing production and trade.
Keywords:  Made in China    Structural Change    International Trade    Manufacturing
JEL分类号:  O11   O14   O41  
基金资助: * 本文感谢国家自然科学基金项目(71973156、71973006)、广东省自然科学基金项目(2019A1515011287)资助。感谢匿名审稿人的宝贵意见,文责自负。
通讯作者:  陈 昊,经济学博士研究生,北京大学光华管理学院,E-mail:hchen@stu.pku. edu.cn.   
作者简介:  郭凯明,经济学博士,副教授,中山大学岭南学院,E-mail:guokm3@mail.sysu.edu.cn.颜 色,经济学博士,副教授,北京大学光华管理学院,E-mail:seyan@gsm.pku.edu.cn.
引用本文:    
郭凯明, 陈昊, 颜色. 贸易成本与中国制造[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 501(3): 1-19.
GUO Kaiming, CHEN Hao, YAN Se. Trade Cost and “Made in China”. Journal of Financial Research, 2022, 501(3): 1-19.
链接本文:  
http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/  或          http://www.jryj.org.cn/CN/Y2022/V501/I3/1
[1]盖庆恩、方聪龙、朱喜和程名望, 2019,《贸易成本、劳动力市场扭曲与中国的劳动生产率》,《管理世界》第3期,第64~80页。
[2]郭凯明、杭静和颜色,2017,《中国改革开放以来产业结构转型的影响因素》,《经济研究》第3期,第32~46页。
[3]郭凯明、余靖雯和吴泽雄,2018,《投资、结构转型与劳动生产率增长》,《金融研究》第3期,第1~16页。
[4]毛其淋和许家云,2016,《中间品贸易自由化与制造业就业变动——来自中国加入WTO的微观证据》,《经济研究》第1期,第69~83页。
[5]颜色、郭凯明和杭静,2018,《需求结构变迁, 产业结构转型和生产率提高》,《经济研究》第12期,第83~96页。
[6]颜色、郭凯明和段雪琴,2021,《老龄化、消费结构与服务业发展》,《金融研究》第2期,第20~37页。
[7]余淼杰,2010,《中国的贸易自由化与制造业企业生产率》,《经济研究》第12期,第97~110页。
[8]余淼杰和梁中华,2014,《贸易自由化与中国劳动收入份额——基于制造业贸易企业数据的实证分析》,《管理世界》第7期,第22~31页。
[9]张艳、唐宜红和周默涵,2013,《服务贸易自由化是否提高了制造业企业生产效率》,《世界经济》第11期,第51~71页。
[10]Acemoglu, Daron, and Veronica Guerrieri. 2008. “Capital Deepening and Nonbalanced Economic Growth” Journal of Political Economy, 116(3): 467~498.
[11]Brandt, Loren, Johannes Van Biesebroeck, Luhang Wang, and Yifan Zhang. 2017. “WTO Accession and Performance of Chinese Manufacturing Firms” American Economic Review, 107(9): 2784~2820.
[12]Caliendo, Lorenzo, Maximiliano Dvorkin, and Fernando Parro. 2019. “Trade and Labor Market Dynamics: General Equilibrium Analysis of the China Trade Shock” Econometrica, 87(3): 741~835.
[13]Comin, Diego, Danial Lashkari, and Marti Mestieri. 2021. “Structural Change with Long‐run Income and Price Effects” Econometrica, 89(1): 311~374.
[14]Defever, Fabrice, Michele Imbruno, and Richard Kneller. 2020. “Trade Liberalization, Input Intermediaries and Firm Productivity: Evidence from China” Journal of International Economics, 126: 103329.
[15]Di Giovanni, Julian, Andrei A. Levchenko, and Jing Zhang. 2014. “The Global Welfare Impact of China: Trade Integration and Technological Change” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 6(3): 153~83.
[16]Eaton, Jonathan, and Samuel Kortum. 2002. “Technology, Geography, and Trade” Econometrica, 70(5): 1741~1779.
[17]Erten, Bilge, and Jessica Leight. 2021. “Exporting out of Agriculture: The Impact of WTO Accession on Structural Transformation in China” Review of Economics and Statistics, 103(2): 364~380.
[18]Facchini, Giovanni, Maggie Y. Liu, Anna Maria Mayda and Minghai Zhou. 2019. “China's ‘Great Migration’: The Impact of the Reduction in Trade Policy Uncertainty” Journal of International Economics, 120: 126~144.
[19]Feng, Ling, Zhiyuan Li and Deborah L. Swenson. 2017. “Trade Policy Uncertainty and Exports: Evidence from China's WTO Accession” Journal of International Economics, 106: 20~36.
[20]Guo, Kaiming, Jing Hang, and Se Yan. 2021. “Servicification of Investment and Structural Transformation: The Case of China” China Economic Review, 67: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chieco.2021.101621.
[21]Handley, Kyle, and Nuno Limao. 2017. “Policy Uncertainty, Trade, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for China and the United States” American Economic Review, 107(9): 2731~83.
[22]Herrendorf, Berthold, Richard Rogerson, and Akos Valentinyi. 2021. “Structural Change in Investment and Consumption-A Unified Analysis” The Review of Economic Studies, 88(3): 1311~1346.
[23]Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Ralph Ossa. 2016. “A Global View of Productivity Growth in China” Journal of International Economics, 102: 209~224.
[24]Kehoe, Timothy J., Kim J. Ruhl, and Joseph B. Steinberg. 2018. “Global Imbalances and Structural Change in the United States” Journal of Political Economy, 126(2): 796~961.
[25]Kongsamut, Piyabha, Sergio Rebelo, and Danyang Xie. 2001. “Beyond Balanced Growth” The Review of Economic Studies, 68(4): 869~882.
[26]Ngai, L. Rachel, and Christopher A. Pissarides. 2007. “Structural Change in a Multisector Model of Growth” American Economic Review, 97(1): 429~443.
[27]Sposi, Michael. 2019. “Evolving Comparative Advantage, Sectoral Linkages, and Structural Change” Journal of Monetary Economics, 103: 75~87.
[28]Swiecki, Tomasz. 2017. “Determinants of Structural Change” Review of Economic Dynamics, 24: 95~131.
[29]Tombe, Trevor, and Xiaodong Zhu. 2019. “Trade, Migration, and Productivity: A Quantitative Analysis of China” American Economic Review, 109(5): 1843~1872.
[30]Uy, Timothy, Kei-Mu Yi, and Jing Zhang. 2013. “Structural Change in an Open Economy” Journal of Monetary Economics, 60(6): 667~682.
[31]Yu, Miaojie. 2015. “Processing Trade, Tariff Reductions and Firm Productivity: Evidence from Chinese Firms” The Economic Journal, 125(585): 943~988.
[1] 皮建才, 宋大强. 中国制造业与房地产业协调发展的测度与判断[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 495(9): 72-90.
[2] 颜色, 郭凯明, 段雪琴. 老龄化、消费结构与服务业发展[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 488(2): 20-37.
[3] 许家云. 进口与企业员工收入——以中国制造业企业为例[J]. 金融研究, 2020, 484(10): 131-149.
[4] 张斌, 熊婉婷. 经济结构转型与“双支柱”调控框架[J]. 金融研究, 2019, 474(12): 92-105.
[5] 李瑞琴, 王汀汀, 胡翠. FDI与中国企业出口产品质量升级——基于上下游产业关联的微观检验[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 456(6): 91-108.
[6] 张斌, 何晓贝, 邓欢. 不一样的杠杆——从国际比较看杠杆上升的现象、原因与影响[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 452(2): 15-29.
[7] 罗长远, 毛成学, 柴晴圆. 美国对外直接投资:中国是一个特别的目的地吗?[J]. 金融研究, 2018, 462(12): 72-90.
[8] 严成樑, 徐翔. 生产性财政支出与结构转型[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 435(9): 99-114.
[9] 吕越, 罗伟, 刘斌. 融资约束与制造业的全球价值链跃升[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 432(6): 81-96.
[10] 杨斌, 朱未名, 赵海英. 供应商主导型的供应链金融模式研究[J]. 金融研究, 2016, 438(12): 175-190.
[11] 许家云, 佟家栋, 毛其淋. 人民币汇率与企业生产率变动——来自中国的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2015, 424(10): 1-16.
[1] 许宪春, 刘婉琪, 彭慧, 张钟文. 新时代全面建成小康社会的辉煌成就及新征程展望——基于“中国平衡发展指数”的综合分析[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 496(10): 1 -21 .
[2] 张国峰, 陆毅, 蒋灵多. 关税冲击与中国进口行为[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 496(10): 40 -58 .
[3] 毛其淋, 盛斌. 劳动力成本对中国加工贸易规模及转型升级的影响[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 496(10): 59 -77 .
[4] 庄毓敏, 张祎. 流动性覆盖率监管会影响货币政策传导效率吗?——来自中国银行业的证据[J]. 金融研究, 2021, 497(11): 1 -21 .
[5] 李波, 朱太辉. 债务杠杆、财务脆弱性与家庭异质性消费行为[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 501(3): 20 -40 .
[6] 明雷, 秦晓雨, 杨胜刚. 差别化存款保险费率与银行风险承担——基于我国农村银行的经验证据[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 501(3): 41 -59 .
[7] 张杰, 王文凯. 方言多样化和企业创新——中国的事实及机制[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 501(3): 135 -151 .
[8] 魏晓云, 韩立岩. 绿色PPP项目组合的最优契约:经济与环境效应的福利视角[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 501(3): 60 -78 .
[9] 刘海明, 步晓宁. 民营企业债务违约是内因驱动吗?——基于短贷长投和多元化经营视角的分析[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 501(3): 79 -95 .
[10] 王筱筱, 李时宇, 袁诚. 政府补贴和国有参股对参与PPP企业外部融资的影响[J]. 金融研究, 2022, 501(3): 96 -114 .
Viewed
Full text


Abstract

Cited

  Shared   
  Discussed   
版权所有 © 《金融研究》编辑部
本系统由北京玛格泰克科技发展有限公司设计开发 技术支持:support@magtech.com.cn
京ICP备11029882号-1