|
|
Taylor Rule Construction and Rule Interest Rate Estimation in China |
SHAN Qiang, LV Jinzhong, WANG Weibin, HUANG Ning
|
Fuzhou Central Sub-Branch, the People's Bank of China; Shanghai Head Office, the People's Bank of China |
|
|
Abstract With the accelerating development of market-oriented interest rate reform and financial innovation, quantitative targets have begun to show limitations. Relying only on quantitative targets can no longer meet the needs of China's monetary policy (Yi, 2018). The central banks of major countries have gradually abandoned their quantitative targets and turned to interest rate monetary policy regulation since the mid-1980s, with their interest rate decisions implicitly following the “Taylor rules” (Sun et al., 2018). China's monetary policy targets are mainly based on inflation and simultaneously adhere to multiple targets (Zhou, 2013), leaving the monetary authority to face more complex constraints. In the process of monetary policy transformation, exploring the Taylor rules in line with China's reality and achieving reasonable rule interest rates are very important to facilitate the transition to price-oriented monetary policy regulation. Many scholars have explored the suitability of different Taylor rules. However, regardless of the Taylor rule used, it cannot be achieved without proper estimations of the potential output and natural interest rate (also referred to as the equilibrium real interest rate). This paper explores the construction of Taylor rules in line with China's reality. It recalculates the potential output embedded with financial cycle factors and the natural interest rate. Furthermore, it estimates rule interest rates to provide useful suggestions for the transformation of monetary policy regulation. This paper estimates the potential output and shows that the output gap embedded with financial cycle factors may decrease the potential output during financial expansion periods. This can help policymakers effectively cope with economic overheating and provide policy guidance for bubble states. The results also show that adding financial cycle proxy variables, such as credit/housing information, has significant explanatory power. Furthermore, this paper measures the natural interest rate (with R001 as the nominal interest rate) using the state space model proposed by Cour-Thimann et al. (2006). From 2004 to 2018, the natural interest rate in China ranged from approximately 0.68% to 3.96%, with an average of approximately 2.35%. The natural interest rate directly estimated by the Hodrick-Prescott filter and the commonly used difference between the nominal interest rate and Consumer Price Index were negative on average, inconsistent with China's reality. This paper verifies the rationality of constructed Taylor rules and estimates the rule interest rates under different circumstances. In addition to the traditional output and inflation factors, it is reasonable to incorporate spreads at home and abroad and the degree of house price deviation from economic growth into Taylor rule construction in China. According to the trends of several calculated rule interest rates, the gap between the money market interest rates and the rule interest rates has significantly narrowed with the rapid progress of market-oriented interest rate reform since 2013. However, their independent trends significantly deviated from the fourth quarter of 2017 to the fourth quarter of 2018. It is necessary to continue to deepen the reform of interest rate liberalization, firmly push the transformation of monetary policy regulation toward price orientation, strengthen policy coordination to provide the necessary policy space for interest rate control, smooth the interest rate transmission channel, improve the effectiveness of interest rate policy transmission, pay more attention to financial cycle factors and strengthen the estimation of natural rate indicators. This paper makes three contributions. First, it includes financial cycle factors in its estimation of China's potential output, which is rare in domestic studies. Second, it uses a method based on the potential output to estimate the natural interest rate, reducing the impacts of setting the model incorrectly. Third, it constructs Taylor rules in line with China's reality and measures the rule interest rates under different circumstances, thereby providing a useful exploration of the transformation of monetary policy regulation.
|
Received: 03 June 2019
Published: 02 October 2020
|
|
|
|
[1] |
陈创练、郑挺国和姚树洁,2016,《时变参数泰勒规则及央行货币政策取向研究》,《经济研究》第8期,第43~51页。
|
[2] |
高丽和李季刚,2013,《双轨制利率体系下我国货币政策反应函数的估计与检验》,《上海金融》第6期,第39~51页。
|
[3] |
江春和陈永,2014,《中国利率市场化阶段利率规则探究_基于对泰勒规则的扩展》,《财贸研究》第3期,第100~107页。
|
[4] |
李宏瑾,2012,《基于标准泰勒规则的我国货币市场利率偏离估算》,《金融评论》第2期,第43~53页。
|
[5] |
李宏瑾和苏乃芳,2016a,《自然利率估算方法文献综述》,《国际金融研究》第6期,第24~35页。
|
[6] |
李宏瑾和苏乃芳,2016b,《货币理论与货币政策中的自然利率及其估算》,《世界经济》第12期,第22~46页
|
[7] |
李宏瑾、苏乃芳和洪浩,2016,《价格型货币政策调控中的实际利率锚》,《经济研究》第1期,第42~54页。
|
[8] |
陆军和钟丹,2003,《泰勒规则在中国的协整检验》,《经济研究》第8期,第76~85页。
|
[9] |
孙国峰、纪敏、牛慕鸿、李宏瑾、钟震和孙莎,2018,《探索符合中国实际的利率调控泰勒规则》,《金融研究报告专报》第10期。
|
[10] |
谢平和罗雄,2002,《泰勒规则及其在中国货币政策中的检验》,《经济研究》第3期,第3~12页。
|
[11] |
熊海芳和王志强,2013,《利率平滑与央行政策偏好的非对称性》,《金融研究》第11期,第41~54页。
|
[12] |
徐忠,2018,《经济高质量发展阶段的中国货币调控方式转型》,《金融研究》第4期,第1~19页。
|
[13] |
易纲,2018,《货币政策回顾与展望》,《中国金融》第2期,第9~11页。
|
[14] |
张晓晶和王宇,2016,《金融周期与创新宏观调控新维度》,《经济学动态》第7期,第12~20页。
|
[15] |
张屹山和张代强,2007,《前瞻性货币政策反应函数在我国货币政策中的检验》,《经济研究》第3期,第20~32页。
|
[16] |
郑挺国和王霞,2011,《泰勒规则的实时分析及其在我国货币政策中的适用性》,《金融研究》第8期,第31~46页。
|
[17] |
周小川,2013,《新世纪以来中国货币政策的主要特点》,《中国金融》第2期,第9~12页。
|
[18] |
Borio, C., 2012, “The Financial Cycle and Macroeconomics: What Have We Learnt?”, BIS Working Papers, No.395.
|
[19] |
Borio, C., P. Disyatat and M. Juselius, 2013, “Rethinking Potential Output: Embedding Information About the Financial Cycle”, BIS Working Papers, No.404.
|
[20] |
Borio, C., P. Disyatat and M. Juselius, 2014, “A Parsimonious Approach to Incorporating Economic Information in Measures of Potential Output”, BIS Working Papers, No.442.
|
[21] |
Borio, C., P. Disyatat, M. Juselius and P. Rungcharoenkitkul, 2018, “Monetary Policy in the Grip of a Pincer Movement”, IDEAS Working Paper Series from RePEc.
|
[22] |
Cour-Thimann, P., Pilegaard, R. and L. Stracca., 2006, “The Output Gap and the Real Interest Rate Gap in the Euro Area”, Journal of Policy Modeling, 7, pp. 775~790.
|
[23] |
European Central Bank., 2004, “The Natural Real Interest Rate in the Euro Area”, Monthly Bulletin, 5.
|
[24] |
Laubach T., J. Williams, 2003, “Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest”, Review of Economics and Statistics, 4, pp. 1063~1070.
|
[25] |
Neiss, K., E. Nelson., 2003, “The Real-Interest-Rate Gap as An Inflation Indicator”, Macroeconomic Dynamic, pp. 239~262.
|
[26] |
Taylor, J., 1993, “Discretion Versus Policy Rules in Practice”, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, pp. 195~214.
|
[27] |
Taylor, J.,1999, “The Robustness and Efficiency of Monetary Policy Rules as Guidelines for Interest Rate Setting by the European Central Bank”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 43, pp. 655~679.
|
[28] |
Taylor, J.,2001, “The Role of the Exchange Rate in Monetary Policy Rules”, American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 91, pp. 263~267.
|
|
|
|