|
|
Estimating Demand Price Elasticity for the Resident Basic Medical Insurance Plan: A Discussion on Reforming the Financing Model |
ZHANG Chuanchuan, LIU Laize
|
School of Economics, Zhejiang University and Business School of Xiangtan University; School of Public Affairs, Zhejiang Universities |
|
|
Abstract The Resident Basic Medical Insurance (RBMI) plan, as the largest social medical insurance plan in the world, delivers protective health coverage to all non-working groups in China, with the goal of ensuring the affordability of medical services. As a basic medical insurance program designed to cover the entire population, RBMI initially charged residents extremely low premiums and was maintained by high financial subsidies. Nonetheless, in recent years, rising medical expenses and mounting financial strain have resulted in an increase in RBMI premiums, and its average growth rate has exceeded China's high-speed per capita GDP growth rate. Due to the voluntary enrollment principle and the quota contribution model, which means that residents in the same region pay the same premium regardless of their family's income and wealth, rising premiums may lead to more and more people not being covered by the program. Recent decreases in RBMI enrolment underscore this worsening predicament. Therefore, the accurate estimation of RBMI demand price elasticity has become an increasingly important prerequisite for the reasonable formulation of individual premium standards and the improvement of the medical insurance financing model. Analyzing data from the China Health and Retirement Longitudinal Survey, a two-way fixed-effect model is used to estimate the price elasticity of RBMI demand. The results show that at the national level in 2022, a 10% upsurge in RBMI's individual premium standard significantly reduces enrolment probability by 0.15%, potentially leaving millions uninsured. The results of the heterogeneity analysis of groups with different characteristics show that compared with high-income groups, the demand price elasticity of middle-income groups is significantly higher. Furthermore, due to the original lower participation rate of low-income groups, the increase in premium standards is expected to crowd out the basic medical insurance needs of people with lower socioeconomic status. We note an adverse selection issue where fewer healthy individuals exhibit higher demand price elasticity, opting to stay in the program and thereby potentially escalating per capita healthcare costs and thwarting RBMI's goal of balancing income and expenditure via premium increases. Compared with residents in urban areas, residents in rural areas, which lack formal jobs, are more likely to be the target population of RBMI. As a result, the insurance needs of rural residents' families are higher. This paper demonstrates that the enrollment decisions of rural residents make them more susceptible to the impact of increasing premium standards. Our subsequent analyses provide empirical evidence that linking payment standards to local residents' per capita disposable income can ameliorate the decline in RBMI coverage. Through a comparative analysis of different types of financing models, this paper outlines the policy implications for the development of RBMI financing models. First, in the process of premium adjustment, the price elasticity of the demand of the insured group should be considered. Furthermore, to increase coverage and balance out one's contribution burden, differentiated premium standards should be set according to the difference in the demand price elasticity. Second, the subsidy scope of low-income people who participate in RBMI should be expanded under the existing quota contribution model. In addition, the low-income subsidy model, which has a lower requirement for income accounting, should be improved. Third, the financing model should be gradually reformed from a quota contribution model to a rate model (i.e., based on family income and property), given that a more powerful and effective household income and property accounting system has been established. This paper makes three contributions to the literature. First, it provides evidence that premium standards play a fundamental role in enabling the national social medical insurance system to perform the required safeguarding function in developing countries. Second, this paper shows that welfare inequality induced by medical insurance can occur at the early enrollment stage. Finally, it offers an initial rationale for discrepancies in the demand price elasticity of medical insurance across different populations, thereby laying the groundwork for more comprehensive research in the future.
|
Received: 02 June 2023
Published: 02 January 2024
|
|
|
|
[1] |
范红丽、王英成和亓锐,2021,《城乡统筹医保与健康实质公平——跨越农村“健康贫困”陷阱》,《中国农村经济》第4期,第69~84页。
|
[2] |
封进、王贞和宋弘,2018,《中国医疗保险体系中的自选择与医疗费用——基于灵活就业人员参保行为的研究》,《金融研究》第8期,第85~101页。
|
[3] |
[日]高山宪之和王新梅,2018,《日本公共养老金制度设计如何借鉴国际经验? 》,《社会保障评论》第3期,第22~29页。
|
[4] |
金双华、于洁和田人合,2020,《中国基本医疗保险制度促进受益公平吗?——基于中国家庭金融调查的实证分析》,《经济学(季刊)》第4期,第1291~1314页。
|
[5] |
李燕凌和李立清,2009,《新型农村合作医疗农户参与行为分析——基于Probit模型的半参数估计》,《中国农村经济》第9期,第63~75页。
|
[6] |
李珍和蒋浩琛,2021,《参保机制视域下韩国国民健康保险制度嬗变及其借鉴》,《社会保障评论》第1期,第78~89页。
|
[7] |
马超、李植乐、孙转兰和唐润宇,2021,《养老金对缓解农村居民医疗负担的作用——为何补贴收入的效果好于补贴医保》,《中国工业经济》第4期,第43~61页。
|
[8] |
王超群、胡杨、张超、陈兆婷和陶丽丽,2022,《从定额制到费率制——代理家计调查视角下城乡居民医保个人缴费标准设定》,《中国卫生政策研究》第10期,第10~17页。
|
[9] |
王红漫、顾大男、杜远举、邓喜先和王宏艳,2006,《新型农村合作医疗参与、满意度及持续性的影响因素分析》,《中国人口科学》第5期,第42~49+95~96页。
|
[10] |
臧文斌、赵绍阳和刘国恩,2013,《城镇基本医疗保险中逆向选择的检验》,《经济学(季刊)》第1期,第47~70页。
|
[11] |
张川川和胡志成,2016,《政府信任与社会公共政策参与——以基层选举投票和社会医疗保险参与为例》,《经济学动态》第3期,第67~77页。
|
[12] |
张川川、魏旭和黄炜,2023,《社会保障项目之间的相互作用:新型农村社会养老保险对医疗保险的挤出》,《经济学(季刊)》第3期,第860~875页。
|
[13] |
赵绍阳、陈钰晓和何庆红,2020,《新生儿未参保之谜:基本事实、成因及其影响》,《中国工业经济》第4期,第61~78页。
|
[14] |
周钦、田森和潘杰,2016,《均等下的不公——城镇居民基本医疗保险受益公平性的理论与实证研究》,《经济研究》第6期,第172~185页。
|
[15] |
朱信凯和彭廷军,2009,《新型农村合作医疗中的“逆向选择”问题:理论研究与实证分析》,《管理世界》第1期,第79~88页。
|
[16] |
Abadie, A., S. Athey, G. W. Imbens, and J. M. Wooldridge, 2023, “When Should you Adjust Standard Errors for Clustering?,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 138(1), pp.1~35.
|
[17] |
Baillon, A., J. Capuno, O. O'Donnell, C. A. Tan Jr, and K. van Wilgenburg, 2022, “Persistent Effects of Temporary Incentives: Evidence From a Nationwide Health Insurance Experiment,” Journal of Health Economics, 81, 102580.
|
[18] |
Banerjee, A., A. Finkelstein, R. Hanna, B. A. Olken, A. Ornaghi, and S. Sumarto, 2021, “The Challenges of Universal Health Insurance in Developing Countries: Experimental Evidence From Lndonesia's National Health Insurance,” American Economic Review, 111(9), pp.3035~3063.
|
[19] |
Cabral, M., M. Geruso, and N. Mahoney, 2018, “Do Larger health Insurance Subsidies Benefit Patients or Producers? Evidence From Medicare Advantage,” American Economic Review, 108(8), pp.2048~2087.
|
[20] |
Capuno, J. J., A. D. Kraft, S. Quimbo, C. R. Tan Jr, and A. Wagstaff, 2016, “Effects of Price, Information, and Transactions Cost Interventions to Raise Voluntary Enrollment in a Social Health Insurance Scheme: A Randomized Experiment in the Philippines,” Health Economics, 25(6), pp.650~662.
|
[21] |
Finkelstein, A., N. Hendren, and M. Shepard, 2019, “Subsidizing Health Insurance for Low-income Adults: Evidence From Massachusetts,” American Economic Review, 109(4), pp.1530~1567.
|
[22] |
Hackmann, M. B., J. T. Kolstad, and A. E. Kowalski, 2012, “Health Reform, Health Insurance, and Selection: Estimating Selection into Health Insurance Using the Massachusetts Health Reform,” American Economic Review, 102(3), pp.498~501.
|
[23] |
MacKinnon J. G., M. Ø. Nielsen, and M. D. Webb, 2023, “Cluster-robust Inference: A guide to Empirical Practice,” Journal of Econometrics, 232(2), pp.272~299.
|
[24] |
Thornton, R. L., L. E. Hatt, E. M. Field, M. Islam, F. Solís Diaz, and M. A. González, 2010, “Social Security Health Insurance for the Informal Sector in Nicaragua: a Randomized Evaluation,” Health Economics, 19(S1), pp.181~206.
|
[25] |
Zhou, M., H. Wang, X. Zeng, et al.,2019, “Mortality, Morbidity, and Risk Factors in China and Its Provinces, 1990-2017: A Systematic Analysis for the Global Burden of Disease Study 2017,” Lancet,394(10204), pp.1145~1158.
|
|
|
|