|
|
Commercial Interest Rates in China from the 17th to the early 20th Century: A Study Based on the Evolution of Financial Organizations |
PENG Kaixiang, CHEN Zhiwu, YUAN Weipeng
|
School of Economics and Management, Wuhan University; Business School, University of Hong Kong; School of Humanities, Shanghai Jiao Tong University |
|
|
Abstract Due to a lack of systematic commercial interest rate data, reasearches about the economic history of the Ming and Qing dynasties mainly draws conclusions based on the descriptions of interest rates in non-commercial private lending. The data problems lead some scholars to believe that higher interest rates hinder economic development and lead to “a great divergence” between China and the West, while others believe that although there is an interest rate difference between China and the West, Smithian growth suggests that non-market channels such as kinship relationships are still sufficient to support China's development. To solve the data problem, we establish a database of interest rate history since the 17th century, drawn from a combination of commercial documents including letters, account books, bank records, and more general material including contracts, judicial records, diaries, notes, and investigation reports. To construct meaningful interest rate series from these various sources, we first identify the evolution of financial organizations from the middle and late Ming dynasty to the late Qing dynasty. We reveal that during this period, pawn shops, silver money shops, exchange shops, and an interbank lending market appeared one after another, and successively became the hubs of commercial financing in each stage. Although traditional financial institutions have lost out in their competition with modern financial institutions such as banks, this does not mean that previous developments should be ignored. Before the 20th century, the evolution of traditional financial organizations and the changes in their business and technology were not without breakthroughs, which provided the conditions for the development of modern finance. These activities were closely related to the large-scale, long-distance capital flows of the period, and the market at the time was close to the capital markets examined in the literature, or close to the “highest level” market defined by Fernand Braudel. Based on this understanding of financial organizations in the Ming and Qing dynasties, we distinguish commercial interest rates from those of non-commercial private lending, and also distinguish the interest rates of ordinary commercial lending from prime commercial lending. Thus, our study reveals that the interest rate showed a general decline in terms of the private lending rate in the late Ming dynasty, particular for commercial lending, which also demonstrated obvious convergence. Although ordinary non-commercial lending interest rates changed little after the late Ming dynasty, the downward trend in commercial interest rates continued into the 19th century, and the lower part (or prime rates) of these rates fell to a greater degree. We also compare interest rates in the “highest level” markets in China and the West, as their business was similar. By the mid-19th century, China's prime rates had fallen to nearly 5% in its advanced regions, although they remained slightly higher than the bill discount rate in London during the same period but were lower or did not exceed similar interest rates for U.S. and Japanese banks. Regional data also show that interest rates for both ordinary and prime lending tended toward integration in the pre/mid-19th century, while the coastal and hinterland “scissors gap” began in the late 19th century. However, the interest rate difference between traditional financial institutions in commercial ports in the late 19th and early 20th centuries was still smaller than that of banks, and close to the regional interest rate difference between U.S. banks when distance is considered. The primary mechanism for promoting the integration of interest rates between commercial ports is through the local interest rate markets formed by the centralized clearing operations of financial institutions. The standardized interest rate formed in these markets plays the role of a price signal, guiding the cross-regional flow of capital and improving the degree of integration of financial markets. The performance of traditional financial institutions is more controversial in terms of enlarging the scale of capital than in terms of their achievements in market organization, particularly compared with modern banks. However, we find no positive relationship between lending scale and interest rate in commercial lending, so the limited size of traditional financial institutions is more likely to be the result of the limited capital demand in the pre-industrial era. In summary, our study demonstrates the evolution of financial organizations in China between the 17th and early 20th centuries, which led to the continuous decline of commercial interest rates and an improvement in interest rate integration. Unlike the typical understanding in the literature, we find that it is not personal arrangements such as kinship networks, but impersonal although informal institutions such as the interest rate market and the periodic clearing system that play a key role. This increases our understanding of Smithian growth and its institutional basis during the Ming and Qing dynasties. Moreover, the interest rate market and other institutions still played a positive role after the rise of banks, which reveals the continuity between the development of traditional and modern finance.
|
Received: 18 August 2022
Published: 02 July 2023
|
|
|
|
[1] |
《康熙中期旅汉口谢氏徽商文书》,2015,《徽州文书(第五辑)》,桂林:广西师范大学出版社。
|
[2] |
《临清州志》,2001,济南:山东省地图出版社。
|
[3] |
《明熹宗实录》,1999,上海:上海书店出版社。
|
[4] |
《吴江县志(嘉靖)》,1987,台北:台湾学生书局。
|
[5] |
《邮传部第三次统计表》,中国第一历史档案馆藏。
|
[6] |
安部健夫,1971,《清代史の研究》,东京:創文社。
|
[7] |
毕自严,2002,《度支奏议》,《续修四库全书》第484册,上海:上海古籍出版社。
|
[8] |
卞利,2019,《明清时期徽州的清明会及其清明墓祭活动初探》,《安徽史学》第3期,第105~114页。
|
[9] |
布罗代尔,1992,《15至18世纪的物质文明、经济和资本主义(第二卷)》,北京:生活·读书·新知三联书店。
|
[10] |
布罗代尔,1997,《资本主义论丛》,北京:中央编译出版社。
|
[11] |
曹树基,2000,《中国人口史(第四卷)》,上海:复旦大学出版社。
|
[12] |
曹树基,2001,《中国人口史(第五卷)》,上海:复旦大学出版社。
|
[13] |
陈添翼和刘秋根,2020,《嘉道时期北京账局的工商业借贷研究》,《河北师范大学学报(哲学社会科学版)》第6期,第35~47页。
|
[14] |
陈志武、彭凯翔和袁为鹏,2016,《清初至二十世纪前期中国利率史初探——基于中国利率史数据库(1660—2000)的考察》,《清史研究》第4期,第39~54页。
|
[15] |
大清银行清理处,1915,《大清银行始末记》,北京:大清银行清理处。
|
[16] |
东亚同文会,2015,《中国省别全志》,北京:国家图书馆出版社。
|
[17] |
傅岩,2006,《歙纪》,合肥:黄山书社。
|
[18] |
戈兹曼,2017,《千年金融史》,北京:中信出版集团。
|
[19] |
格申克龙,2009,《经济落后的历史透视》,北京:商务印书馆。
|
[20] |
龚关,2007,《近代天津金融业研究(1861—1936)》,天津:天津人民出版社。
|
[21] |
顾琳,2009,《中国的经济革命:二十世纪的乡村工业》,南京:江苏人民出版社。
|
[22] |
韩大成,1991,《明代城市研究》,北京:中国人民大学出版社。
|
[23] |
黄鉴晖,2002,《山西票号史》,太原:山西经济出版社。
|
[24] |
黄鉴晖等,2002,《山西票号史料》,太原:山西经济出版社。
|
[25] |
黄宗智,1992,《长江三角洲小农家庭与乡村发展》,北京:中华书局。
|
[26] |
江晓成,2017,《清代的京债与地方吏治》,《清史研究》第1期,第94~105页。
|
[27] |
孔祥毅,2004,《镖局、标期、标利与中国北方社会信用》,《金融研究》第1期,第117~125页。
|
[28] |
刘秋根,2000,《明清高利贷资本》,北京:社会科学文献出版社。
|
[29] |
彭凯翔,2015,《从交易到市场:传统中国民间经济脉络试探》,杭州:浙江大学出版社。
|
[30] |
彭凯翔,2021,《崇祯十五年借兑客标考:兼论明清之际的南北银流与军事财政》,中山大学历史系(珠海)“中国经济史中的粮料、财用与价格”学术研讨会讨论稿。
|
[31] |
彭凯翔、陈志武和袁为鹏,2008,《近代中国农村借贷市场的机制》,《经济研究》第5期,第147~159页。
|
[32] |
彭慕兰,2003,《大分流:欧洲、中国及现代世界经济的发展》,南京:江苏人民出版社。
|
[33] |
乔幼梅,1988,《宋元时期高利贷资本的发展》,《中国社会科学》第3期,第200~222页。
|
[34] |
邱澎生,2005,《也是“商法”问题:试论十七世纪中国的法律批判与法律推理》,《法制史研究:中国法制史学会会刊》第8期,第75~123页。
|
[35] |
史若民,1998,《票商兴衰史》,北京:中国经济出版社。
|
[36] |
宋怡明,2019,《被统治的艺术:中华帝国晚期的日常政治》,北京:中国华侨出版社。
|
[37] |
许檀,2011,《乾隆—道光年间的北洋贸易与上海的崛起》,《学术月刊》第11期,第147~154页。
|
[38] |
严中平,1955,《中国棉纺织史稿》,北京:科学出版社。
|
[39] |
杨荫溥,1936,《杨著中国金融论》,上海:黎明书局。
|
[40] |
叶世昌,2002,《中国金融通史(第一卷)》,北京:中国金融出版社。
|
[41] |
袁采,1935,《袁氏世范》,上海:商务印书馆。
|
[42] |
张宇燕和高程,2005,《海外白银、初始制度条件与东方世界的停滞——关于晚明中国何以“错过”经济起飞历史机遇的猜想》,《经济学(季刊)》第2期,第491~518页。
|
[43] |
郑亦芳,1981,《上海钱庄(一八四三~一九三七)——中国传统金融业的蜕变》,台北:中研院三民主义研究所。
|
[44] |
郑振满,2009,《明清福建家族组织与社会变迁》,北京:中国人民大学出版社。
|
[45] |
朱荫贵,2007,《论近代中国企业商号吸收社会储蓄——1930年南京政府禁令颁布前后的分析》,《复旦大学学报》(社会科学版)第5期,第96~106页。
|
[46] |
朱荫贵,2021,《近代中国的资本市场:生成与演变》,上海:复旦大学出版社。
|
[47] |
Bodenhorn, H. 1992. “Capital Mobility and Financial Integration in Antebellum America”, The Journal of Economic History, 52(3): 585~610.
|
[48] |
Elvin, M. 1973. The Pattern of the Chinese Past, Stanford University Press .
|
[49] |
Grief, A. 1993. “Contract Enforceability and Economic Institutions in Early Trade”, The American Economic Review, 83(3): 525~548.
|
[50] |
Homer, S. and R. Sylla. 2005. A History of Interest Rates, Rutgers University Press.
|
[51] |
Keller, W., C. Shiue, and X. Wang. 2021. “Capital Markets in China and Britain, 1770-1860: Evidence from Grain Prices”, American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 13(3): 31~64.
|
[52] |
King, T. C. 2006. History of the London Discount Market, Routledge.
|
[53] |
Liu, W. G. 2015. The Chinese Market Economy, 1000-1500, Albany, Suny Press.
|
[54] |
McDermott, J. P. 2013. The Making of a New Rural Order in South China: I. Village, Land, and Lineage in Huizhou, 900-1600, Cambridge University Press.
|
[55] |
Miwa, Y. and J. M. Ramseyer. 2006. “Japanese Industrial Finance at the Close of the 19th Century: Trade Credit and Financial Intermediation”, Explorations in Economic History, 43(1): 94~118.
|
[56] |
Pomeranz, K. 1993. The Making of a Hinterland: State, Society, and Economy in Inland North China, 1853-1937, University of California Press
|
[57] |
Rosenthal, J. and R. B. Wong. 2011. Before and Beyond Divergence: The Politics of Economic Change in China and Europe, Harvard University Press.
|
[58] |
Rousseau, P. L. and R. Sylla. 2006. “Financial Revolutions and Economic Growth”, Explorations in Economic History, 43(1): 1~12.
|
|
|
|