|
|
Spillover Effects of U.S. Monetary Policy, China's Asset Price Fluctuations and Capital Account Control |
WU Liyuan, ZHAO Fuyang, WANG Chan, GONG Liutang
|
Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Science; School of Economics, Central University of Finance and Economics; School of Finance,Central University of Finance and Economics; School of International Economics and Management, Beijing Technology and Business University; LMEQF, Peking University |
|
|
Abstract A bulk of empirical studies have confirmed the spillover effects of U.S. monetary policy on China and other emerging market countries. The U.S. Federal Reserve resumed its quantitative easing policy in 2020. This resulted in the federal funding rate falling to zero, a dramatic expansion of the Federal Reserve's balance sheet, and a global flood of liquidity. Currently, the U.S. economy is gradually recovering, and inflation is rising.It is therefore expected that the Federal Reserve will soon tighten monetary policy and increase the federal funding rate. This implies that emerging market countries, including China, may once again experience a shortage of liquidity and interest rate hikes, in contrast to the current extremely fluid monetary policy. This raises the following three key questions. What are the spillover effects of U.S. monetary policy on China's economy? What is the mechanism of such spillover effects? What policies could stabilize the fluctuations caused by these spillover effects? This paper aims to answer these questions with reference to the Federal Reserve's interest rate hike in 2016. Based on Davis and Presno(2017),we contruct a small open economy dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model(DSGE)with financial friction and a real estate market.We thereby propose the causative mechanism as follows:The increase in U.S. interest rates generates externalities in the flow of capital, which accelerates the decline of domestic asset prices. This triggers the first feedback channel, which is driven by financial friction, leading to the synergistic decline of domestic investment and asset prices. Thus, the expected return on domestic assets is reduced, which triggers a second feedback channel and further increases capital outflows. In addition,we use welfare analysis to determine the optimal level of capital account control and its effect on the independence of monetary policy. This reveals the optimal level of capital account control should be moderate, as such control has two opposing effects: capital account control can effectively alleviate the influence of foreign interest-rate shocks on economic fluctuations while it can also decrease the efficient allocation of national wealth. The optimal level of capital account control must therefore balance macro-prudence and efficiency. What's more,we find that appropriate policies for capital account control help to enhance the independence of monetary policy. In contrast to previous studies, we simultaneously replicate and explicate, within a unified framework, the characteristics of China's macroeconomy subsequent to the U.S. Federal Reserve's interest rate hike in 2016. We also propose a mechanism for the interaction between the feedback channels of capital flow externalities and financial accelerators, which links the spillover effects of U.S. monetary policy with asset price fluctuations. This confirms that China's real estate market is a key channel via which U.S. monetary shocks affect China's economy. Based on the above findings, we make the following policy recommendations. First, capital account control should be gradually transformed to capital account management. This requires the gradual liberalization of long-term capital account restrictions and the establishment of a regular mechanism for the management of abnormal capital flows. Second, more market-oriented dynamic measures for capital account management should be explored, such as risk reserves, Tobin taxes, and macro-prudential taxes. Third, while the opening of the capital account is gradually and steadily promoted, policies should be developed to increase reform depth and risk prevention. Increasing reform depth requires the marketization of the RMB exchange rate formation mechanism and the opening of the financial market, whereas increasing risk prevention requires the gradual implementation of policy experiments in lower risk fields.
|
Received: 15 October 2018
Published: 02 August 2021
|
|
|
|
[1] |
傅广敏,2017,《美联储加息、人民币汇率与价格波动》,《国际贸易问题》第3期,第131~142页。
|
[2] |
顾海峰和卞雨晨,2020,《跨境资本流动、资产价格与银行流动性风险——货币政策不确定性与银行业竞争的调节作用》,《财经科学》第12期,第13~27页。
|
[3] |
郝大鹏、王博和李力,2020,《美联储政策变化、国际资本流动与宏观经济波动》,《金融研究》第7期,第38~56页。
|
[4] |
何国华和李洁,2017,《跨境资本流动、金融波动与货币政策选择》,《国际金融研究》第9期,第3~13页。
|
[5] |
何青、钱宗鑫和郭俊杰,2015,《房地产驱动了中国经济周期吗?》,《经济研究》第12期,第41~53页。
|
[6] |
侯成琪和龚六堂,2014,《货币政策应该对住房价格波动作出反应吗——基于两部门动态随机一般均衡模型的分析》,《金融研究》第10期,第15~33页。
|
[7] |
姜富伟、郭鹏和郭豫媚,2019,《美联储货币政策对我国资产价格的影响》,《金融研究》第5期,第37~55页。
|
[8] |
李力、王博、刘潇潇和郝大鹏,2016,《短期资本、货币政策和金融稳定》,《金融研究》第9期,第18~32页。
|
[9] |
林细细和龚六堂,2007,《生产性公共开支经济中政府债务的福利损失》,《管理世界》第8期,第4~11页。
|
[10] |
刘传哲和陈慧莹,2018,《美联储加息对资本市场的影响研究——基于时变视角下的分析》,《价格理论与实践》第5期,第107~110页。
|
[11] |
王博和王开元,2018,《汇率改革、短期国际资本流动与资产价格》,《金融论坛》第4期,第56~68页。
|
[12] |
王冠楠和项卫星,2017,《金融摩擦与宏观经济的外部脆弱性——基于美联储加息政策的分析视角》,《国际金融研究》第7期,第13~23页。
|
[13] |
王频和侯成琪,2017,《预期冲击、房价波动与经济波动》,《经济研究》第4期,第48~63页。
|
[14] |
王申和陶士贵,2015,《人民币汇率、短期国际资本流动与资产价格》,《金融论坛》第7期,第59~70页。
|
[15] |
温兴春和梅冬州,2020,《金融业开放、金融脆弱性以及危机跨部门传递》,《世界经济》第10期,第144~168页。
|
[16] |
严成樑,2020,《通货膨胀的产业结构变迁效应与社会福利损失》,《世界经济》第2期,第49~73页。
|
[17] |
张勇,2015,《热钱流入、外汇冲销与汇率干预——基于资本管制和央行资产负债表的DSGE分析》,《经济研究》第7期,第116~130页。
|
[18] |
赵扶扬、王忏和龚六堂,2017,《土地财政与中国经济波动》,《经济研究》第12期,第46~61页。
|
[19] |
朱孟楠、丁冰茜和闫帅,2017,《人民币汇率预期、短期国际资本流动与房价》,《世界经济研究》第7期,第17~29页。
|
[20] |
朱孟楠和闫帅,2017,《异质性投资视角下短期国际资本流动与资产价格》,《国际金融研究》第2期,第36~44页。
|
[21] |
庄子罐、崔小勇、龚六堂和邹恒甫,2012,《预期与经济波动——预期冲击是驱动中国经济波动的主要力量吗?》,《经济研究》第6期,第46~59页。
|
[22] |
Bianchi, J., 2011. “Overborrowing and Systemic Externalities in the Business Cycle”, The American Economic Review, 101(7): 3400~3426.
|
[23] |
Bianchi, C. A., 2013. “Housing Cycles and Macroeconomic Fluctuations: A Global Perspective”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 37: 215~238.
|
[24] |
Bianchi, C. A., A. Ferrero and A. Rebucci, 2018. “International Credit Supply Shocks”, Journal of International Economics, 112: 219~237.
|
[25] |
Bianchi, C. A., L. F. Cespedes and A. Rebucci, 2015, Global Liquidity, House Prices, and the Macroeconomy:Evidence from Advanced and Emerging Economies, INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND.
|
[26] |
Calvo, G. A., 1983. “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(3): 383~398.
|
[27] |
Chang, C., Z. Liu and M. M. Spiegel, 2015. “Capital Controls and Optimal Chinese Monetary Policy”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 74: 1~15.
|
[28] |
Christiano, L. J., R. Motto and M. Rostagno, 2014. “Risk Shocks”, American Economic Review, 104(1): 27~65.
|
[29] |
Davis, J. S. and I. Presno, 2017. “Capital Controls and Monetary Policy Autonomy in a Small Open Economy”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 85: 114~130.
|
[30] |
Eickmeier, S. and T. Ng, 2015. “How Do US Credit Supply Shocks Propagate Internationally? A GVAR Approach”, European Economic Review, 74: 128~145.
|
[31] |
Engel, C., 2011. “Currency Misalignments and Optimal Monetary Policy: A Reexamination”, American Economic Review, 101(6): 2796~2822.
|
[32] |
Galí, J., 2015, Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework and its Applications, Princeton University Press.
|
[33] |
Galí, J. and T. Monacelli, 2005. “Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy”, The Review of Economic Studies, 72(3): 707~734.
|
[34] |
Gong, L., C. Wang and H. Zou, 2016. “Optimal Monetary Policy with International Trade in Intermediate Inputs”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 65: 140~165.
|
[35] |
Huang, X., T. Jin and J. Zhang, 2018. “Monetary Policy, Hot Money and Housing Price Growth Across Chinese Cities”, Hot Money and Housing Price Growth Across Chinese Cities (October 25, 2018).
|
[36] |
Hummels, D., 1999. “Toward a Geography of Trade Costs”.
|
[37] |
Iacoviello, M. and S. Neri, 2010. “Housing Market Spillovers: Evidence from an Estimated DSGE Model”, American Economic Journal. Macroeconomics, 2(2): 125~164.
|
[38] |
Kiyotaki, N. and J. Moore, 1997. “Credit Cycles”, The Journal of Political Economy, 105(2): 211~248.
|
[39] |
Liu, Z., P. Wang and T. Zha, 2013. “Land‐Price Dynamics and Macroeconomic Fluctuations”, Econometrica, 81(3): 1147~1184.
|
[40] |
Neely, C. J., 2015. “Unconventional Monetary Policy Had Large International Effects”, Journal of Banking & Finance, 52: 101~111.
|
[41] |
Schmitt-Grohé, S. and M. Uribe, 2003. “Closing Small Open Economy Models”, Journal of International Economics, 61(1): 163~185.
|
[42] |
Schmitt-Grohé, S. and M. Uribe, 2012. “What's News in Business Cycles”, Econometrica, 80(6): 2733~2764.
|
[43] |
Schmitt-Grohé, S. and M. Uribe, 2016. “Downward Nominal Wage Rigidity, Currency Pegs, and Involuntary Unemployment”, The Journal of Political Economy, 124(5): 1466~1514.
|
[44] |
Smets, F. and R. Wouters, 2007. “Shocks and Frictions in US Business Cycles: A Bayesian DSGE Approach”, The American Economic Review, 97(3): 586~606.
|
[45] |
Uribe, M. and V. Z. Yue, 2006. “Country Spreads and Emerging Countries: Who Drives Whom?”, Journal of International Economics, 69(1): 6~36.
|
|
|
|