|
|
How Increasing Tariffs Affects the U.S. Trade Deficit and Global Welfare: An Analysis Based on a Two-Country Dynamic General Equilibrium Framework Incorporating the Dollar Standard |
LIU Kai
|
School of Economics/Institute of China's Economic Reform & Development, Renmin University of China |
|
|
Abstract During recent years protectionism has come to dominate U.S. trade policy. The U.S. has tried to narrow its long-standing large trade deficit and to protect its industries by imposing tariffs on other countries, refusing to support multilateral trading systems, and by other means. Relevant data show that since the collapse of the Bretton Woods system and the establishment of the Jamaican system in the 1970s, the global economic imbalances that are exemplified by the U.S. trade deficit have continued for more than 40 years. Although these imbalances have shown some volatility, in essence they are a set of long-term phenomena. In addition, the U.S. has maintained a long-term trade deficit with almost all of its main trading partners, not just China, and thus the U.S. trade deficit is also a structural phenomenon. In fact, the dollar-standard characteristic of the current international monetary system is one of the root causes of the long-term U.S. trade deficit. The questions explored in this paper are as follows. If the important role of the dollar standard in determining the persistent U.S. trade deficit is taken into account, can the U.S. tariffs draw down the size of the U.S. trade deficit, and how do these tariffs affect the welfare of global residents? What would happen if other economies retaliated against the U.S.? In the face of a U.S.-sponsored trade war, could weakening the dollar standard boost the welfare of other economies? To answer these questions, this paper constructs a two-country dynamic general equilibrium model that incorporates the characteristics of the dollar standard. Based on this model, the paper analyzes the impacts of U.S. tariffs and the trade war on both the U.S. trade deficit and on global welfare, while discussing the relevant transmission mechanism in detail. Under the benchmark model setting, if the U.S. unilaterally imposes an extra 20% tariff, it will reduce the U.S. trade deficit-GDP ratio by about 0.40 percentage points. In addition, the U.S. long-term steady-state GDP will fall by about 2.50%, while the overall GDP of other countries will fall by about 1.10%. U.S. welfare will rise by about 0.60%, and the welfare of other countries will fall by about 1.20%. The unilateral increase in tariffs imposed by the U.S. will curb global trade and production, and worsen the distribution of global welfare through unfair terms of international trade. When other countries take retaliatory measures, that is, when the trade war breaks out, the welfare of other countries will not deteriorate further, but U.S. welfare will fall sharply, and the relative scale of the U.S. trade deficit will not change much. The “prisoner's dilemma” feature of the trade war game can, to a certain extent, explain the occurrence of the trade war. Weakening the dollar standard can help to promote fairness in international trade, which can weaken the negative impacts of the trade war, raise the level of global welfare, and effectively narrow the U.S. trade deficit. This paper offers two main contributions to the existing literature. First, it analyzes the long-term effects that the U.S. tariffs and trade war have on the U.S. trade deficit and on global economic imbalances. This analysis involves constructing a quantitative macroeconomic general equilibrium model, which has been lacking in the existing literature. Second, this paper discusses the impacts of the U.S. tariff and trade war with full consideration for the factor of the dollar standard, which is one important factor that has been neglected in the existing literature. Therefore, this paper's analysis is better aligned with the reality of the world economy than previous studies.
|
Received: 19 April 2019
Published: 30 December 2020
|
|
|
|
[1] |
陈勇兵、陈小鸿、曹亮和李兵,2014,《中国进口需求弹性的估算》,《世界经济》第2期,第28~49页。
|
[2] |
段玉婉、刘丹阳和倪红福,2018,《全球价值链视角下的关税有效保护率——兼评美国加征关税的影响》,《中国工业经济》第7期,第62~79页。
|
[3] |
樊海潮和张丽娜,2018,《中间品贸易与中美贸易摩擦的福利效应:基于理论与量化分析的研究》, 《中国工业经济》第9期,第41~59页。
|
[4] |
李晓和周学智,2012,《美国对外负债的可持续性:外部调整理论的扩展》, 《世界经济》第12期, 第130~155页。
|
[5] |
刘凯,2017,《美元本位、全球经济失衡与人民币国际化》,《人文杂志》第5期,第54~64页。
|
[6] |
刘凯,2018,《中国特色的土地制度如何影响中国经济增长——基于多部门动态一般均衡框架的分析》,《中国工业经济》第10期,第 80~98页。
|
[7] |
沈琪和周世民,2014,《进口关税减免与企业全要素生产率: 来自中国的微观证据》,《管理世界》第9期, 第174~175页。
|
[8] |
盛斌和毛其淋,2017,《进口贸易自由化是否影响了中国制造业出口技术复杂度》,《世界经济》第12期,第52~75页。
|
[9] |
田巍和余淼杰,2014,《中间品贸易自由化和企业研发: 基于中国数据的经验分析》,《世界经济》第6期,第90~112页。
|
[10] |
仝冰,2017,《混频数据、投资冲击与中国宏观经济波动》,《经济研究》第6期,第60~76页。
|
[11] |
佟苍松和熊晓琳,2007,《美国对进口中国制造业商品执行的关税政策》,《世界经济》第11期,第24~31页。
|
[12] |
王道平和范小云,2011,《现行的国际货币体系是否是全球经济失衡和金融危机的原因》,《世界经济》第1期,第52~72页。
|
[13] |
余淼杰和袁东,2016,《贸易自由化, 加工贸易与成本加成——来自我国制造业企业的证据》,《管理世界》第9期,第33~43页。
|
[14] |
张顺明和余军,2009,《内部货币与我国最优关税政策研究》,《经济研究》第2期,第18~31页。
|
[15] |
Alessandria, G. and H. Choi. 2014. “Establishment Heterogeneity, Exporter Dynamics, and the Effects of Trade Liberalization”, Journal of International Economics, 94(2): 207~223.
|
[16] |
Alves, N., S. Gomes, and J. Sousa. 2007. “An Open Economy Model of the Euro Area and the US”, Banco de Portugal, Economics and Research Department Working Papers, No. W200718.3.4.
|
[17] |
Bagwell, K. and R.W. Staiger. 1999. “An Economic Theory of GATT”, American Economic Review, 89(1): 215~248.
|
[18] |
Bagwell, K. and R.W. Staiger. 2011. “What Do Trade Negotiators Negotiate About? Empirical Evidence from the World Trade Organization”, American Economic Review, 101(4): 1238~1273.
|
[19] |
Caliendo, L., R.C. Feenstra, J. Romalis, and A.M. Taylor. 2015. “Tariff Reductions, Entry, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for the Last Two Decades”, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Papers, No. w21768.
|
[20] |
Caliendo, L. and F. Parro. 2015. “Estimates of the Trade and Welfare Effects of NAFTA”, Review of Economic Studies, 82(1): 1~44.
|
[21] |
Chen, Y., K. Liu, and Z. Liu. 2018. “U.S. Money Supply and China's Business Cycles”, Emerging Markets Finance and Trade, 54(5): 957~980.
|
[22] |
Chu, A.C., G. Cozzi, C. Lai, and C. Liao. 2015. “Inflation, R&D and Growth in an Open Economy”, Journal of International Economics, 96, 360~374.
|
[23] |
Funke, M., M. Paetz, and E. Pytlarczyk. 2010. “Stock Market Wealth Effects in an Estimated DSGE Model for Hong Kong”, Economic Modelling, 28: 316~334.
|
[24] |
Gali, J. and T. Monacelli. 2005. “Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in a Small Open Economy”, Review of Economic Studies, 72(3): 707~734.
|
[25] |
Ganelli, G. and J. Tervala. 2015. “Value of WTO Trade Agreements in a New Keynesian Model”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 45(37): 347~362.
|
[26] |
Handley, K. and N. Limão. 2017. “Policy Uncertainty, Trade, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for China and the United States”, American Economic Review, 107(9): 2731~2783.
|
[27] |
Nisticó, S. 2012. “Monetary Policy and Stock-price Dynamics in a DSGE Framework”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 34: 126~146.
|
[28] |
Ossa, R. 2011. “A ‘New Trade' Theory of GATT/WTO Negotiations”, Journal of Political Economy, 119(1): 122~152.
|
|
|
|