|
|
Trade Friction, Macroeconomic Fluctuations, and the Choice of Economic Openness |
XIAO Zumian, PENG Hongfeng, XIANG Lijin
|
School of Finance, Shandong University of Finance and Economics |
|
|
Abstract Trade friction between China and the United States (US) broke out in early 2018. We can foresee that with the gradual improvement of China's international economic status, Sino-US economic and trade relations will continue to be affected by various forms of friction and conflict. Moreover, it is likely that such frictions and conflicts will exist cyclically in the long run, which will eventually have significant and profound impacts on China's macro-economy. Therefore, it is necessary to analyze the following questions in depth: how will trade frictions affect China's macro-economy? To what extent can China open up its economy? According to international trade theory, a country can impose tariffs to improve its terms of trade and promote net export growth. Therefore, tariff measures are often used as the most direct policy tool when trade frictions occur between two countries. This article introduces tariff shocks, foreign exchange risk premiums, and monetary policy cost channels into a two-country open economy dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model to study the macroeconomic fluctuations caused by trade frictions and analyze relevant policy options for the economic opening of markets. This article decomposes the real exchange rate fluctuations caused by tariff shocks into “direct effects” and “indirect effects” and clarifies the transmission channels and theoretical mechanisms through which tariff shocks affect the terms of trade and the real exchange rate. First, the log-linearization of the real exchange rate equation shows that an increase in tariffs directly triggers the devaluation of the domestic currency. However, these exchange rate changes cannot fully offset the price distortion caused by tariff shocks. Second, after expressing the terms of trade as an equation of the relative output levels of the two countries, tariffs, and foreign exchange risk premiums, we find that tariff shocks deteriorate the terms of trade, which triggers the appreciation of the domestic currency. Therefore, tariff shocks affect the real exchange rate through direct and indirect channels. The results of impulse response analysis show that tariff shocks change the terms of trade and the real exchange rate. Under the current status of China's trade openness, foreign tariffs will not only deteriorate the country's terms of trade, leading to a decline in exports and output, but will also depreciate the country's exchange rate, leading to an increase in exports and output. Overall, for the macro-economy, tariff shocks will induce a minor increase in domestic output and a decline in home inflation, as well as a decline in foreign output levels and an increase in foreign inflation. Moreover, if the domestic government strengthens its control over cross-border capital flows during trade frictions, the terms of trade will deteriorate and cause the real exchange rate to appreciate, which will negatively affect exports and output. A loose monetary policy can directly stimulate output growth and, simultaneously, indirectly increase domestic economic output by depreciating the exchange rate and improving the terms of trade. The results of economic welfare analysis suggest that the government's choice of trade openness and capital account openness significantly affect macroeconomic fluctuations. First, a moderate increase in domestic trade openness leads to a slight increase in economic welfare losses, while the foreign country faces greater welfare losses; an excessive increase in domestic trade openness leads to a sharp increase in domestic welfare losses, which reach a value greater than the welfare losses incurred by the foreign country. Second, in trade frictions, a moderate relaxation of capital controls improves the terms of trade, which depreciates the real exchange rate and increases output. Finally, an increase in foreign tariffs will trigger the devaluation of the domestic currency. The moderate depreciation of the domestic currency helps hedge against the negative impact of tariffs, increase exports, and boost domestic economic output. In conclusion, in the face of the trade frictions, the domestic government should adhere to the principle of increasing trade openness within an appropriate scope and steadily promote capital account liberalization to avoid substantial economic welfare losses. In addition, implementing a loose monetary policy and relaxing the exchange rate daily trading band can help mitigate the negative impacts of trade frictions.
|
Received: 16 May 2019
Published: 02 November 2020
|
|
|
|
[1] |
胡小文和章上峰,2015,《利率市场化、汇率制度改革与资本账户开放顺序安排——基于NOEM-DSGE模型的模拟》,《国际金融研究》第11期,第14~23页。
|
[2] |
黄鹏、汪建新和孟雪,2018,《经济全球化再平衡与中美贸易摩擦》,《中国工业经济》第10期,第156~174页。
|
[3] |
康立和龚六堂,2014,《金融摩擦、银行净资产与国际经济危机传导——基于多部门DSGE模型分析》,《经济研究》第5期,第147~159页。
|
[4] |
李成、姚洁强和王超,2008,《基于博弈理论对中美汇率政策的解析》,《国际金融研究》第7期,第12~17页。
|
[5] |
李春顶、何传添和林创伟,2018,《中美贸易摩擦应对政策的效果评估》,《中国工业经济》第10期,第137~155页。
|
[6] |
林仁文和杨熠,2014,《中国市场化改革与货币政策有效性演变——基于DSGE的模型分析》,《管理世界》第6期,第39-52+187页。
|
[7] |
陆前进,2017,《贸易条件与经常项目的动态变化关系——基于新开放经济宏观经济学框架的理论和“金砖五国”的实证研究》,《金融研究》第5期,第32~46页。
|
[8] |
马勇,2013,《植入金融因素的DSGE模型与宏观审慎货币政策规则》,《世界经济》第7期,第68~92页。
|
[9] |
倪红福、龚六堂和陈湘杰,2018,《全球价值链中的关税成本效应分析——兼论中美贸易摩擦的价格效应和福利效应》,《数量经济技术经济研究》第8期,第74~90页。
|
[10] |
彭红枫、肖祖沔和祝小全,2018,《汇率市场化与资本账户开放的路径选择》,《世界经济》第8期,第26~50页。
|
[11] |
王彬、马文涛和刘胜会,2014,《人民币汇率均衡与失衡:基于一般均衡框架的视角》,《世界经济》第6期,第27~50页。
|
[12] |
庄子罐、崔小勇和赵晓军,2016:《不确定性、宏观经济波动与中国货币政策规则选择——基于贝叶斯DSGE模型的数量分析》,《管理世界》,第11期,第20-31+187页。
|
[13] |
Alessandria, George, and Horag, Choi. 2014. “Establishment Heterogeneity, Exporter Dynamics, and the Effects of Trade Liberalization”, Journal of International Economics, 94(2): 207~223.
|
[14] |
Bagwell, Kyle, and Robert W., Staiger. 1999. “An Economic Theory of GATT”, The American Economic Review, 89(1): 215~248.
|
[15] |
Bagwell, Kyle, and Robert W., Staiger. 2011. “What Do Trade Negotiators Negotiate About? Empirical Evidence from the World Trade Organization” The American Economic Review, 101(4): 1238~1273.
|
[16] |
Broda, Christian. 2004. “Terms of Trade and Exchange Rate Regimes in Developing Countries”, Journal of International Economics, 63(1), 31~58.
|
[17] |
Caliendo, Lorenzo, and Fernando, Parro. 2015. “Estimates of the Trade and Welfare Effects of NAFTA”, The Review of Economic Studies, 82(1): 1~44.
|
[18] |
Calvo, Guillermo A. 1983. “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(3): 383~398.
|
[19] |
Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin, Eichenbaum, and Charles L., Evans. 2005. “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of A Shock to Monetary Policy”, Journal of Political Economy, 113(1): 1~45.
|
[20] |
Clarida, Richard, Jordi, Gali, and Mark, Gertler. 2002. “A Simple Framework for International Monetary Policy Analysis”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 49(5): 879~904.
|
[21] |
Eaton, Jonathan, and Samuel, Kortum. 2002. “Technology, Geography, and Trade”, Econometrica, 70(5): 1741~1779.
|
[22] |
Engel, Charles M. 2011. “Currency Misalignments and Optimal Monetary Policy: A Reexamination”, The American Economic Review, 101(6): 2796~2822.
|
[23] |
Fender, John, and Chong K., Yip. 2000. “Tariffs and Exchange Rate Dynamics Redux”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 19(5): 633~655.
|
[24] |
Gali, Jordi, and Tommaso, Monacelli. 2005. “Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Volatility in A Small Open Economy”, The Review of Economic Studies, 72(3): 707~734.
|
[25] |
Ganelli, Giovanni, and Juha, Tervala. 2015. “Value of WTO Trade Agreements in A New Keynesian Model”, Journal of Macroeconomics, 45(37): 347~362.
|
[26] |
Johnson, Harry G. 1953. “Optimum Tariffs and Retaliation”, Review of Economic Studies, 21(2):142~153.
|
[27] |
Kose, Ayhan M. 2002. “Explaining Business Cycles in Small Open Economies: How Much Do World Prices Matter?”, Journal of International Economics, 56(2): 299~327.
|
[28] |
Lindé, Jesper, and Andrea Pescatori. 2019. “The Macroeconomic Effects of Trade Tariffs: Revisiting the Lerner Symmetry Result”, Journal of International Money and Finance, 95:52~69.
|
[29] |
Mendoza, Enrique G. 1991. “Real Business Cycles in a Small Open Economy”, The American Economic Review, 81(4): 797~818.
|
[30] |
Ossa, Ralph. 2011. “A 'New Trade' Theory of GATT/WTO Negotiations”, Journal of Political Economy, 119(1): 122~152.
|
[31] |
Ossa, Ralph. 2014. “Trade Wars and Trade Talks with Data”, The American Economic Review, 104(12): 4104~4146.
|
[32] |
Ravenna, Federico and Carl E., Walsh. 2006. “Optimal Monetary Policy with the Cost Channel”, Journal of Monetary Economics, 53(2): 199~216.
|
[33] |
Schmitt-Grohé, Stephanie and Martín, Uribe. 2018. “How important are terms of trade shocks?”, International Economic Review, 59(1): 85~111.
|
[34] |
Smets. Frank and Raf, Wouters. 2003. “An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area”, Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(5): 1123~1175.
|
[35] |
Svensson, Lars E.O. 2000. “Open-Economy Inflation Targeting”, Journal of International Economics, 50(1): 155~183.
|
[36] |
Woodford, Michael. 2003. “Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy” Princeton University Press.
|
|
|
|