|
|
When can I Go Home?School Provisioning and the Decision to Immigrate |
LI Ming, ZHENG Liming
|
School of International Trade and Economics, University of International Business and Economics |
|
|
Abstract In recent years, the existing population of China has begun to relocate among different cities.This is exemplified by a new trend among China's massive migrant population of returning to their hometowns.With the relaxation of the Hukou system, it is worth considering how to promote the reasonable and orderly flow of labor and improve the efficiency of human resource allocation.Many factors influence migration.Tiebout proposed that residents flow into the region that best matches their preferences, after considering the public goods and tax levels of each location.Studies of developed countries suggest that this mechanism exists (Bayoh et al., 2006;Kleven et al., 2013;Dustmann and Okatenko, 2014;Akcigit et al., 2016;Moretti and Wilson, 2017).However, due to the uniform tax system and Hukou system in China, the effectiveness of the Tiebout model is debated, especially in the context of populations returning to their hometowns. We empirically investigate the causal effect of public goods supply on a migrants' decisions to return to their hometowns.We obtain data on residential address and “usual place of residence five years ago” from the 2005 National Sample Survey to construct a dynamic variable denoting whether migrants return to their hometowns.We also construct a proxy variable for change in the number of schools at the city level according to the extended implementation of the “School Consolidation” policy in China.This is a public policy promoted in China since 2001 that aims to improve the quality of education by eliminating many smaller schools and merging them into larger institutions.Using a quasi-natural experimental approach, we divide the sample into treat and control groups based on the presence of children aged 6-10 years in the family (a child was 10 years old in 2005 when the data was collected, given that he/she started primary school at 6 years of age in 2001) and build a difference-in-differences model. Our findings are as follows.First, a decrease in the number of schools significantly hinders the return of the migrant population.Furthermore, the greater the decrease in the number of schools, the greater the negative impact on the return of the migrant population.This result still holds when considering endogeneity and other factors.Second, the results of our heterogeneity analysis show that the impact above is valid for both rural and urban areas and is more obvious among smaller families and families with boys.Third, the impact is not only on parents but also on their school-age children, meaning that the availability of educational public goods affects the migration decisions of two generations. Beyond confirming the Tiebout model, this paper contributes to the literature in at least in two additional ways.First, we demonstrate the impact of public goods on migrants returning home and enrich the literature in this field.Most existing studies exploring the impact of public services on migration are based on an outflow perspective, and little attention has been paid to returning inflows.Further, due to limited data, the available studies are more theoretical in nature.Second, our identification setup is new.We attempt to explore the dynamics of migration based on cross-sectional census data at the household level, which may inform future studies. The conclusions of this paper are informative in the context of policy decisions.In developing countries, improving the efficiency of public resource distribution and optimizing the provision of public goods such as education could help break down barriers to labor mobility and thus further promote economic growth and quality of life.For cities trying to attract talent, enhancing the provisioning of public goods could help to stimulate further population inflows.In this paper, we focus on the impact of changes in the number of schools.Future studies could assess the impacts of public education quality or other public goods (e.g., health care) to explore the effect of public goods supply on population mobility to a broader and deeper extent.
|
Received: 29 April 2020
Published: 02 May 2021
|
|
|
|
[1] |
丁冬和郑风田,2015,《撤点并校:整合教育资源还是减少教育投入?—基于1996—2009年的省级面板数据分析》,《经济学(季刊)》第14卷第2期,第603~622页。
|
[2] |
丁延庆、王绍达和叶晓阳,2016,《为什么有些地方政府撤并了更多农村学校》,《教育经济评论》第1卷第4期,第3~34页。
|
[3] |
付文林,2007,《人口流动的结构性障碍:基于公共支出竞争的经验分析》,《世界经济》第12期,第32~40页。
|
[4] |
黎嘉辉,2019,《城市房价、公共品与流动人口留城意愿》,《财经研究》第6期,第86~100页。
|
[5] |
李斌、李拓和朱业,2015,《公共服务均等化、民生财政支出与城市化—基于中国286个城市面板数据的动态空间计量检验》,《中国软科学》第6期,第79~90页。
|
[6] |
李超、万海远和田志磊,2018,《为教育而流动—随迁子女教育政策改革对农民工流动的影响》,《财贸经济》第1期,第132~146页。
|
[7] |
李明和张亦然,2019,《空气污染的移民效应—基于来华留学生高校-城市选择的研究》,《经济研究》第6期,第168~182页。
|
[8] |
梁超和王素素,2020,《教育公共品配置调整对人力资本的影响——基于撤点并校的研究》,《经济研究》第9期,第138~154页。
|
[9] |
梁若冰和汤韵,2008,《地方公共品供给中的Tiebout模型—基于中国城市房价的经验研究》,《世界经济》第10期,第71~83页。
|
[10] |
卢珂和杜育红,2010,《农村学校布局调整对学生成绩的影响—基于两水平增值模型的分析》,《清华大学教育研究》第31卷第6期,第64~73页。
|
[11] |
陆铭、高虹和佐藤宏,2012,《城市规模与包容性就业》,《中国社会科学》第10期,第47~66页。
|
[12] |
乔宝云、范剑勇和冯兴元,2005,《中国的财政分权与小学义务教育》,《中国社会科学》第6期,第37~46页。
|
[13] |
宋弘和吴茂华,2020,《高房价是否导致了区域高技能人力资本流出?》,《金融研究》第3期,第77~95页。
|
[14] |
汪德华、邹杰和毛中根,2019,《“扶教育之贫”的增智与增收效应—对20世纪90年代“国家贫困地区义务教育工程”的评估》,《经济研究》第9期,第155~171页。
|
[15] |
吴伟平和刘乃全,2016,《异质性公共支出对劳动力迁移的门槛效应:理论模型与经验分析》,《财贸经济》第3期,第28~44页。
|
[16] |
夏纪军,2004,《人口流动性、公共收入与支出—户籍制度变迁动因分析》,《经济研究》第10期,第56~65页。
|
[17] |
夏怡然和陆铭,2015,《城市间的“孟母三迁”—公共服务影响劳动力流向的经验研究》,《管理世界》第10期,第78~90页。
|
[18] |
邢春冰和李实,2011,《扩招“大跃进”、教育机会与大学毕业生就业》,《经济学(季刊)》第10卷第4期,第1187~1208页。
|
[19] |
张晏、夏纪军和张文瑾,2010,《自上而下的标尺竞争与中国省级政府公共支出溢出效应差异》,《浙江社会科学》第12期,第20~26+74页。
|
[20] |
周黎安,2007,《中国地方官员的晋升锦标赛模式研究》,《经济研究》第7期,第36~50页。
|
[21] |
Aaronson, D.and B.Mazumder, 2011, “The Impact of Rosenwald Schools on Black Achievement ”, Journal of Political Economy, 119(5): 821~888.
|
[22] |
Akcigit, U., S.Baslandze and S.Stantcheva, 2016, “Taxation and the International Mobility of Inventors”, American Economic Review, 106(10): 2930~2981.
|
[23] |
Angrist, J.D.and V.Lavy, 1999, “Using Maimonides' Rule to Estimate the Effect of Class Size on Scholastic Achievement ”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(2): 533~575.
|
[24] |
Bayoh, I., E.Irwin and T.Haab, 2006, “Determinants of Residential Location Choice: How Important are Local Public Goods in Attracting Homeowners to Central City Locations? ”, Journal of Regional Science, 46(1): 97~120.
|
[25] |
Conley, T.G., C.B.Hansen and P.E.Rossi, 2012, “Plausibly Exogenous”, The Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(1): 260~272.
|
[26] |
Dahlberg, M., M.Eklof, P.Fredriksson and J.Jofremonseny, 2012, “Estimating Preferences for Local Public Services Using Migration Data”, Urban Studies, 49(2): 319~336.
|
[27] |
Day, K.M., 1992, “Interprovincial Migration and Local Public Goods”, The Canadian Journal of Economics, 25(1): 123~144.
|
[28] |
Duflo, E., 2001, “Schooling and Labor Market Consequences of School Construction in Indonesia: Evidence from an Unusual Policy Experiment”, American Economic Review, 91(4): 795~813.
|
[29] |
Dustmann, C.and A.Okatenko, 2014, “Out-Migration, Wealth Constraints, and The Quality of Local Amenities”, Journal of Development Economics, 110: 52~63.
|
[30] |
Kleven, H.J., C.Landais and E.Saez, 2013, “Taxation and International Migration of Superstars: Evidence from the European Football Market”, American Economic Review, 103(5): 1892~1924.
|
[31] |
Kleven, H.J., C.Landais, E.Saez and E.A.Schultz, 2014, “Migration and Wage Effects of Taxing Top Earners: Evidence from the Foreigners' Tax Scheme in Denmark”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(1): 333~378.
|
[32] |
Krueger, A.B., 1999, “Experimental Estimates of Education Production Functions”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(2): 497~532.
|
[33] |
Liu, J.and C.Xing, 2016, “Migrate for Education: An Unintended Effect of School District Combination in Rural China”, China Economic Review, 40: 192~206.
|
[34] |
Liu, Q.and Y.Lu, 2015, “Firm Investment and Exporting: Evidence from China's Value-added Tax Reform ”, Journal of International Economics, 97(2): 392~403.
|
[35] |
Moretti, E.and D.J.Wilson, 2017, “The Effect of State Taxes on the Geographical Location of Top Earners: Evidence from Star Scientists”, American Economic Review, 107(7): 1858~1903.
|
[36] |
Nunn, N.and L.Wantchekon, 2011, “The Slave Trade and the Origins of Mistrust in Africa”, American Economic Review, 101(7): 3221~3252.
|
|
|
|