|
|
Economic Transition and the Two-Pillar Framework |
ZHANG Bin, XIONG Wanting
|
Institute of World Economics and Politics, Chinese Academy of Social Sciences |
|
|
Abstract The implementation and coordination of monetary policy and macro prudential policy require an awareness of changes in the underlying macroeconomic environment.Since 2012, China has been in the process of structual transition, from a manufacturing economy to a service economy, with rising shares of human capital intensive industries (HCIIs). Structural transitions in the real economy impact the stability of the macro economy and the financial market. Recently, the major risk to macroeconomic stability has shifted from overheating to overcooling. To stabilize macroeconomic performance, the growth in aggregate demand should be consistent with the growth in aggregate supply. The inconsistency in this relationship is indicated by the inflation rate. During the 2002-2012 period, the general price index, the GDP deflator, was as high as 4.7%, suggesting that the economy was overheating, showing the signs of aggregate demand outgrowing aggregate supply. Growth in aggregate demand is driven by growth in nominal purchasing power, which is caused by credit expansion. Credit expansion is mainly supported by the expansion of firms in capital-intensive industries. After 2012, the economic conditions changed. The average GDP deflator in the 2012-2018 period dropped by 3% to 1.8%. The price index for producers, PPI, witnessed a continuous drop for 18 quarters. There were two reasons for this phenomenon. First, there was a decrease in market-driven demand for credit by firms because HCIIs require less investment than capital intensive industries. Second, banks reduced the credit supply to startup firms in HCIIs due to their lack of collateral and credit records. As for the financial stability, the post-crisis reflections on systemic risks mainly focused on the issues of overheating and excessive risk taking, which sets the background for systemic risk has become the pressure of overcooling and insufficient risk preference. However, China is now experiencing a structural transition characterized by weak external demand. Therefore, the sources of systemic risk are now overcooling and insufficient risk taking. In the temporal dimension , new systemic risks stem from the downside pressure of both economic and financial cycles and their mutual reinforcement. In the spatial dimension, the source of contagion riskno longer “too big to fall” systemically important banks, but small financial institutions with big impacts and diversified business models. Since the implementation of the Macro-Prudential Assessment (MPA) framework in 2016, big banks that are identified as systemically important institutions have significantly improved the robustness of their balance sheets, but small and medium institutions, including urban commercial banks, rural commercial banks, and private banks, are facing larger risks. Given these issues, we use the “double pillar” regulation framework to make three key suggestions for managing the macro-economy and financial systems in a period of economic transition. First, monetary policy should not try to achieve too many goals; instead, it should prioritize the stabilization of aggregate demand and the achievement of moderate inflation. The major challenge for achieving these goals is the insufficient credit demand by firms and credit supply by traditional banks as a result of transitions in industrial structures. In the long term, the solution to this problem is to implement structural reforms of the financial system that give a bigger role to equity financing tools, as they provide better financial service to HCIIs and satisfy their market-driven financing needs. In the short term, more policy measures should be adopted, such as more flexible adjustment of the policy rate, lifting of loan restrictions in certain industries,and the coordinated implimentation of fiscal policy. Second, policy makers should consider the new systemic risks in their design of the MPA, and make improvements to related policy tools and supporting systems. To tackle the systemic risks related to troubled institutions that are small, offer diversified services, and have extensive potential impacts, we suggest three improvements to the current regulatory framework. First, to restrict high cost and high risk financial services, more of the currently unregulated financial innovations should be included in the regulatory framework. Second, there should be a stress test that considers the possibility of the simultaneous market exit of large numbers of small and medium institutions. Third, there is a need to establish a series of firewalls to prevent the contagion and aggravation of risks arising from the exit of troubled institutions. Third, the coordination of monetary policy and prudential regulations should take into consideration the current structure of China's financial system and make an effort to reduce the imbalance between the demand of the real sector and the supply of financial services. At the same time, adopting a moderately loose monetary policy could provide a buffer against the constraining effect of more stringent prudential regulations on credit supply, thus reducing the risk of the simultaneous bankruptcy of multiple problematic financial institutions and mutually enhancing the financial and economic cycles.
|
Received: 09 September 2019
Published: 13 January 2020
|
|
|
|
[1] |
陈雨露,2019,《四十年来中央银行的研究进展及中国的实践》,《金融研究》第2期,第1~19页。
|
[2] |
马勇,2013,《宏观审慎的动态方法论基础》,《金融评论》第3期,第25~42页。
|
[3] |
马勇和陈雨露,2013,《宏观审慎政策的协调与搭配:基于中国的模拟分析》,《金融研究》第8期,第 61~73页。
|
[4] |
马勇、张靖岚和陈雨露,2017,《金融周期与货币政策》,《金融研究》第3期,第37~57页。
|
[5] |
(美)瑞·达利欧《债务危机:我的应对原则》,中信出版集团,2019年3月。
|
[6] |
王爱俭和王璟怡,2014,《宏观审慎政策效应及其与货币政策关系研究》,《经济研究》第4期,第17~31页。
|
[7] |
张斌,2015,《从制造到服务:经验、理论与中国问题》,《比较》第5期。
|
[8] |
张斌和邹静娴,2018,《中国经济结构转型的进展与差距》,《国际经济评论》第6期,第9~24页。
|
[9] |
张斌、何晓贝和邓欢,2018,《不一样的杠杆——从国际比较看杠杆上升的现象、原因与影响》,《金融研究》第2期,第15~29页。
|
[10] |
中国人民银行,2018,《中国金融稳定报告2018》,中国金融出版社。
|
[11] |
周莉萍,2018,《货币政策与宏观审慎政策研究:共识、分歧与展望》,《经济学动态》第10期,第102~117页。
|
[12] |
周小川,2011,《金融政策对金融危机的响应——宏观审慎政策框架的形成背景、内在逻辑和主要内容》,《金融研究》第1期,第1~14页。
|
[13] |
Akinci, O. and Olmstead-Rumsey, J. 2018. “How effective are macroprudential policies? An empirical investigation”,Journal of Financial Intermediation, 2018 (33),pp. 33~57.
|
[14] |
Angelini, P., Neri, S. and Panetta, F. 2011. “Monetary and Macroprudential Policies”, Temi di discussione.
|
[15] |
Bernanke, B. 1983. “Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression”,The American Economic Review,73(3),pp. 257~276.
|
[16] |
BIS. 2018. “Moving forward with macroprudential frameworks”, BIS Annual Economic Report, https://www.bis.orgpublarpdf/ar2018e4.htm.
|
[17] |
Boar, C., Gambacorta, L., Lombardo, G., and Pereira, S. L. 2017. “What are the Effects of Macroprudential Policies on Macroeconomic Performance? ”,BIS Quarterly Review.
|
[18] |
Buera, F.J. and Kaboski J.P. 2012. “The Rise of the Service Economy” ,American Economic Review, 102(6), pp. 2540~69.
|
[19] |
Cerutti, E., Claessens, S., and Laeven,L. 2017. “The Use and Effectiveness of Macroprudential Policies: New Evidence”,Journal of Financial Stability, 28, pp. 203~224.
|
[20] |
Claessens, S. 2016. “Regulation And Structural Change In Financial Systems”,ECB Forum on Central Banking.
|
[21] |
Dunstan, A. 2014. “The Interaction Between Monetary and Macro-prudential Policy”,Reserve Bank Bulletin, 77, Reserve Bank of New Zealand, No.11.
|
[22] |
Eggertsson, G. B. and Krugman P. 2012. “Debt,Deleveraging,and the Liquidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo Approach”,The Quarterly Journal of Economics,127(3), pp.1469~1513
|
[23] |
Filardo, A. and Rungcharoenkitkul, P. 2016. “A Quantitative Vase for Leaning against the Wind”. BIS Working Papers, No.594.
|
[24] |
Fisher, I. 1933. “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions”,Econometrica, 1(4), pp.337~357.
|
[25] |
Galati, G. and Moessner, R. 2018. “What Do We Know About the Effects of Macroprudential Policy? ”, Economica, 85(340): 735~770.
|
[26] |
Koo, R. 2001. “The Japanese Economy in Balance Sheet Recession: The Real Culprit is Fallacy of Composition, not Complacency”,Business Economics, 36(2), pp.15~23.
|
[27] |
Sato, T.2014. “Macroprudential Policy and Initiatives by the Bank of Japan”, Speech at Japan Society in London, http://www.boj.or.jp/en/announcements/press/koen_2014datako141112b1.pdf.
|
[28] |
Svensson, L.E.O. 2018. “Monetary Policy and Macroprudential Policy: Different and Separate? ”,Canadian Journal of Economics,51(3), pp. 802~827.
|
[29] |
Ubide, A. 2015. “Interaction Between Monetary Policy and Macroprudential Policies: Challenges faced by the ECB”,Peterson Institute for International Economics.
|
|
|
|