|
|
The Dynamic Adjustment of Chinese Households’ Financial Asset Allocation |
XU Jia, TAN Ya
|
Guanghua School of Management,Peking University; Center for Public Economy & Public Policy,Chongqing University |
|
|
Abstract This paper introduces a two-period OLG model which encompasses heterogeneous households and risky markets with different participation costs, it discusses the wealth effect of households’ risky asset allocation under different participation costs. Based on the Oaxaca-Blinder decomposition method, this paper utilizes CHFS 2011 data to prove the prediction of the model: from low wealth level, households first prefer indirect participation in risky asset, and will increase their direct participation as households’ wealth accumulates.
|
Received: 01 July 2016
Published: 01 January 1900
|
|
|
|
[1] |
吴卫星和齐天翔,2007,《流动性,生命周期与投资组合的相异性》,《经济研究》第2期,第97~110页。
|
[2] |
吴卫星、丘艳春和张琳琬,2015,《中国居民家庭投资组合有效性: 基于夏普率的研究》,《世界经济》第1期,第154~172页。
|
[3] |
谭松涛和陈玉宇,2012,《投资经验能够改善股民的收益状况吗——基于股民交易记录数据的研究》,《金融研究》第5期,第164~178页。
|
[4] |
甘犁,2015,《中国家庭金融调查报告: 2014》. 西南财经大学出版社.
|
[5] |
Abel, A. B., 2001, “The Effects of Investing Social Security Funds In The Stock Market When Fixed Costs Prevent Some Households From Holding Stocks,” American Economic Review, 98(1),128-148.
|
[6] |
Bricker, J., A. B. Kennickell, K. B. Moore and J. Sabelhaus, 2012, “Changes in US Family Finances from 2007 to 2010: Evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, 98(2), pp. 1~80.
|
[7] |
Campbell, J. Y., 2006, “Household Finance,” Journal of Finance, 61(4), pp. 1553~1604.
|
[8] |
Cardak, B. A. and R. Wilkins, 2009, “The Determinants of Household Risky Asset Holdings: Australian Evidence on Background Risk and other Factors,” Journal of Banking & Finance, 33(5), pp. 850~860.
|
[9] |
Carroll, C., 2002, “Portfolios of the Rich,” Household portfolios, ed. Guiso, L., Haliassos, M., Jappelli, T. MIT Press, 2002.
|
[10] |
Cocco, J. F., F. J. Gomes and P. J. Maenhout, 2005, “Consumption and Portfolio Choice over the Life Cycle,” Review of Financial Studies, 18(2), pp. 491~533.
|
[11] |
Grossman, S. and G. Laroque, 1990, “Asset Pricing and Optimal Portfolio Choice in the Presence of Illiquid Consumption Goods,” Econometrica, 58, pp. 25~52.
|
[12] |
Guiso, L. and T. Jappelli, 2002, “Household Portfolios in Italy,” Household portfolios, ed. Guiso, L., Haliassos, M., Jappelli, T. MIT Press, 2002, pp. 251~290.
|
[13] |
Guiso, L. and M. Paiella, 2008, “Risk Aversion, Wealth, and Background Risk,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(6), pp. 1109~1150.
|
[14] |
Heaton, J. and D. Lucas, 2000. “Portfolio Choice and Asset Prices: The Importance of Entrepreneurial Risk,” Journal of Finance, 55(3), pp. 1163~1198.
|
[15] |
Iwaisako, T., 2009, “Household Portfolios in Japan,” Japan and the World Economy, 21(4), pp. 373~382.
|
[16] |
Ivkovic',Z.,C.Sialm and S.Weisbenner,2008,“Portfolio Concentration and the Performance of Individual Investors,”Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis,43(3),pp.613~655.
|
[17] |
King, M. A. and J. Leape, 1998, “Wealth and Portfolio Composition: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Public Economics, 69(2), pp. 155~193.
|
[18] |
Paxson,C.,1990,“Borrowing Constraints and Portfolio Choice,”The Quarterly Journal of Economics,105(2),pp.535~543.
|
[19] |
Wachter, J. A. and M. Yogo, 2010, “Why Do Household Portfolio Shares Rise in Wealth?” Review of Financial Studies, 23(11), pp. 3929~3965.
|
[20] |
Vissing-Jorgensen, A., 2002,“Towards an Explanation of Household Portfolio Choice Heterogeneity: Nonfinancial Income and Participation Cost Structures,” NBER Working No. w8884.
|
|
|
|