|
|
The Gender Gap in the Labor Market, Structural Transformation, and Demographic Transition |
GUO Kaiming, WANG Yubing, YAN Se
|
Lingnan College, Sun Yat-sen University; Guanghua School of Management, Peking University |
|
|
Abstract The modernization of China is inextricably linked to its population. China is undergoing a rapid demographic transition, with a falling fertility rate, an aging population, and a shrinking population dividend. China's labor force has been decreasing since 2015, and its population peaked around 2021. Meanwhile, China's economy is undergoing a salient structural transformation, with a new technological revolution, a new wave of industrial change, and a rapid increase in high-tech manufacturing and modern services on the horizon. This structural transformation may affect population growth, while the demographic transition may also affect the structure of the economy. The relationship between these two processes and the related effects require comprehensive study to help China promote long-term, balanced population growth and promote structural transformation during this new development stage. We propose a new theoretical mechanism of the gender gap in the labor market to better understand the relationship between structural transformation and demographic transition. Our novel dynamic general equilibrium model incorporates the endogenous evolution of the gender gap in the labor market, structural transformation, and population growth. The model also allows us to fully capture the structural effects of related policies, such as directly intervening in the price of female labor or lowering fertility costs. We focus on the gender gap in the labor market for three main reasons. First, the share of female employment differs greatly among sectors in China, and the sectoral shares of output vary. Second, the industries with the largest share of female labor are mostly skill-intensive. Skilled labor relies on mental labor, whereas unskilled labor relies on physical labor. Compared with male workers, female workers have an advantage in supplying mental labor relative to physical labor. Third, women have an advantage over men in raising children. We find that because the structural transformation process increases the share of mental-labor-intensive sectors, it narrows the gender wage gap, increasing fertility costs and thus decreasing the fertility rate. This in turn increases the relative supply of female labor and mental labor. When the elasticity of substitution between sectoral outputs is high, the share of mental-labor-intensive sectors continues to increase. Hence, the economy experiences a dynamic transition in which the share of mental-labor-intensive sectors increases, the gender wage gap narrows, the relative supply of female labor increases, and the population growth rate falls. We also find that a policy to intervene in the price of female labor, which is intended to narrow the gender wage gap, may instead result in the structural unemployment of women, widen the gender gap in the labor market, and slow structural transformation. A policy to lower women's fertility costs would increase the fertility rate, but it could have the same side effects. In contrast, a policy to lower the fertility costs of men would increase the fertility rate, narrow the gender gap in the labor market, and promote structural transformation. We also find that the adverse effects of subsidizing childbirth may be reduced when sponsored by the government rather than firms. Thus, a policy to further lower men's fertility costs should be coordinated with a policy to lower those of women, with the former sponsored by firms and the latter by the government. We derive the policy implications of these findings by suggesting policies to promote long-term, balanced population growth, narrow the gender gap in the labor market, and spur structural transformation. Moreover, the government should establish policies that simultaneously encourage families to have children, improve the structure of the labor supply, and narrow the gender gap. First, the government should act to reduce the opportunity costs of fertility, particularly for men. Second, the government should reduce the economic burden of having children and support firms with more tax breaks and public spending. Third, the government could also explore alternative ways to increase birth rates through public spending and tax reductions. This paper contributes to the literature by systematically analyzing the relationship between the gender gap in the labor market and China's ongoing structural transformation and demographic transition. The conclusions offer a novel mechanism through which structural transformation and demographic changes affect each other and a comprehensive framework with which to evaluate the structural effects of related policies.
|
Received: 07 June 2022
Published: 16 February 2023
|
|
|
|
[1] |
郭凯明和颜色,2011,《性别偏好与人口转型》,《经济学(季刊)》第4期,第1209~1234页。
|
[2] |
郭凯明和颜色,2015,《性别工资差距、资本积累与人口转变》,《金融研究》第8期,第13~30页。
|
[3] |
郭凯明、颜色和李双潞,2021,《结构转型、生育率选择与人口转变》,《世界经济》第1期,第106~125页。
|
[4] |
汪伟、刘玉飞和彭东东,2015,《人口老龄化的产业结构升级效应研究》,《中国工业经济》第11期,第47~61页。
|
[5] |
鄢伟波和安磊,2021,《中国女性劳动供给为何降低:来自流动人口的证据》,《世界经济》第12期,第104~130页。
|
[6] |
颜色、郭凯明和段雪琴,2021,《老龄化、消费结构与服务业发展》,《金融研究》第2期,第20~37页。
|
[7] |
颜色、郭凯明和杭静,2022,《中国人口红利与产业结构转型》,《管理世界》第4期,第15~33页。
|
[8] |
詹鹏、毛逸波和李实,2021,《城镇女性劳动供给长期趋势研究:来自教育扩张和生育行为的解释》,《中国工业经济》第8期,第56~74页。
|
[9] |
Acemoglu, Daron, and Veronica Guerrieri. 2008. “Capital Deepening and Non-balanced Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy, 116(3):467~498.
|
[10] |
Adda, Jérôme, Christian Dustmann, and Katrien Stevens. 2017, “The Career Costs of Children”, Journal of Political Economy, 125(2):293~337.
|
[11] |
Becker, Gary S., and H. G. Lewis. 1973. “On the Interaction between the Quantity and Quality of Children”, Journal of Political Economy, 81(2):279~288.
|
[12] |
Becker, Gary S., Kevin M. Murphy, and Robert Tamura. 1990. “Human Capital, Fertility, and Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy, 98(5):12~37.
|
[13] |
Bloom, David E., David Canning, Günther Fink, and Jocelyn E. Finlay. 2009. “Fertility, Female Labor Force Participation, and the Demographic Dividend”, Journal of Economic Growth, 14(2):79~101.
|
[14] |
Comin, Diego, Danial Lashkari, and Marti Mestieri. 2021. “Structural Change with Long‐Run Income and Price Effects”, Econometrica, 89(1):311~374.
|
[15] |
Cravino, Javier, Andrei Levchenko, and Marco Rojas. 2022. “Population Aging and Structural Transformation”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 14(4):479~498.
|
[16] |
Ehrlich, Isaac, and Francis T. Lui. 1991. “Intergenerational Trade, Longevity, and Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Economy, 99(5):1029~1059.
|
[17] |
Gaddis, Isis, and Stephan Klasen. 2014. “Economic Development, Structural Change, and Women's Labor Force Participation: A Reexamination of the Feminization U Hypothesis”, Journal of Population Economics, 27(3):639~681.
|
[18] |
Galor, Oded, and David N. Weil. 1996. “The Gender Gap, Fertility, and Growth”, American Economic Review, 86(3):374~387.
|
[19] |
Galor, Oded, and David N. Weil. 2000. “Population, Technology, and Growth: From Malthusian Stagnation to the Demographic Transition and Beyond”, American Economic Review, 90(4):806~828.
|
[20] |
Greenwood, Jeremy, Ananth Seshadri, and Guillaume Vandenbroucke. 2005. “The Baby Boom and Baby Bust”, American Economic Review, 95(1):183~207.
|
[21] |
Kongsamut, Piyabha, Sergio Rebelo, and Dangyang Xie. 2001. “Beyond Balanced Growth”, Review of Economic Studies, 68(4):869~882.
|
[22] |
Lagerlof, Nils-Petter. 2003. “Gender Equality and Long-Run Growth”, Journal of Economic Growth, 8(4):403~426.
|
[23] |
Leukhina, Oksana M., and Stephen J. Turnovsky. 2016. “Population Size Effects in the Structural Development of England”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 8(3):195~229.
|
[24] |
Ngai, L. Rachel, and Barbara Petrongolo. 2017. “Gender Gaps and the Rise of the Service Economy”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 9(4):1~44.
|
[25] |
Ngai, L. Rachel, and Christopher A. Pissarides. 2007. “Structural Change in a Multisector Model of Growth”, American Economic Review, 97(1):429~443.
|
[26] |
Rendall, Michelle. 2013. “Structural Change in Developing Countries:Has it Decreased Gender Inequality?”, World Development, 45:1~16.
|
[27] |
Rendall, Michelle. 2017. “Brain versus Brawn: The Realization of Women's Comparative Advantage”, SSRN Working Paper, no. 491.
|
[28] |
Simonovska, Ina, and Michael E. Waugh. 2011. “Different Trade Models, Different Trade Elasticities?”, NBER Working Paper, no. 16796.
|
[29] |
Strulik, Holger, and Jacob Weisdorf. 2008. “Population, Food, and Knowledge: A Simple Unified Growth Theory”, Journal of Economic Growth, 13(3):195~216.
|
[30] |
Vollrath, Dietrich. 2009. “The Dual Economy in Long-Run Development”, Journal of Economic Growth, 14(4):287~312.
|
[31] |
Wu, Xiaoyu. 2022. “Fertility and Maternal Labor Supply: Evidence from the New Two-Child Policies in Urban China”, Journal of Comparative Economics, 50(2):584~598.
|
|
|
|