|
|
Catch-Up Strategy and Banking Structure: The Perspective of New Structural Economics |
ZHU Yonghua, ZHANG Yilin, LIN Yifu
|
Institute of New Structural Economics, Peking University; Lingnan College, Sun Yat-sen University |
|
|
Abstract Since the start of its economic reform and opening-up in 1978, China has witnessed rapid economic growth. However, this development has been unbalanced, and in the financial market, this imbalance is evidenced by inadequate and expensive financing for small and medium-sized firms, in contrast to the easily obtainable, low-cost funding available to large firms. The literature proposes that small banks can more effectively meet the financing needs of small and medium-sized firms than big banks. China's banking sector is dominated by four state-owned big banks, and entry into the industry is strictly regulated by the government. What drove the Chinese government to restrict the entry of new banks into the industry? Considering China's rapid and sustained economic growth and the lack of a systemic financial crisis in the past four decades, is it economically rational for the government to restrict bank entry and allow the banking system to be monopolized by big banks in the early stage of China's economic reform? This study argues that the deposits of big banks would be partially transferred to newly established small banks such that the total loanable funds available from big banks would sharply decline if the entry barriers to the banking sector were lowered, as capital and total fund supply were scarce in China in the early stages of reform and opening-up. Consequently, the financing costs of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) increase as credit availability decreases because SOEs have enormous capital needs, while newly established banks have a small asset scale and cannot provide large loans to diversify risks effectively. In this scenario, the government's intervention in the banking sector, or the entry barriers to new banks, becomes a sub-optimal arrangement. From a transaction cost perspective, this study discusses how the catch-up strategy determines the banking structure in a country using a static game that includes firms and banks of different sizes. The theoretical analysis in this study focuses on two types of transaction costs when banks lend to firms—contracting and information costs. Contracting costs refer to the real costs incurred when finalizing loan agreements. One key feature of contracting costs is that they nearly change with loan size and can be approximated as fixed costs. The larger the amount of a single loan, the greater the economies of scale, and the lower the contracting cost per unit of financing. Information costs refer to the costs resulting from information asymmetry, such as the labor costs of screening firms and banks' losses from loan defaults. This study shows that considering the contracting and information costs, big banks are in a better position to fund large firms because big banks have the economies of scale to lend to large firms with large capital demands, thereby lowering the transaction costs of financing. In contrast, if one or a few small banks provide large loans to a large firm, they take on a high risk of bankruptcy in the event of a loan default. If small banks are to diversify their investments or limit the sizes of single loans to reduce their risk of bankruptcy, large firms would have to borrow from multiple small banks simultaneously, which would sharply increase the transaction costs of financing. This study provides policy references for further reform and development of China's banking industry. China's industrial landscape is characterized by the presence of a large number of labor-intensive small firms. Hence, this study proposes that local small banks should be developed further and interest rates should be liberalized further to meet the financing needs of small firms.
|
Received: 02 March 2022
Published: 02 December 2022
|
|
|
|
[1] |
陈斌开和林毅夫,2012,《金融抑制、产业结构与收入分配》,《世界经济》第1期,第3~23页。
|
[2] |
贺小海和刘修岩,2008,《中国银行业结构影响因素的实证研究》,《财经研究》第5期,第52~62页。
|
[3] |
李华民,2005,《寡头均衡,绩效改善与金融稳定——中国银行业结构变迁的政策取向》,《金融研究》第8期,第23~36页。
|
[4] |
李一鸣和薛峰,2008,《我国商业银行市场结构现状分析及其优化研究》,《中国工业经济》第11期,第78~87页。
|
[5] |
李志赟,2002,《银行结构与中小企业融资》,《经济研究》第6期,第38~45+94页。
|
[6] |
林毅夫,2002,《发展战略、自生能力和经济收敛》,《经济学(季刊)》第1期,第269~300页。
|
[7] |
林毅夫、孙希芳和姜烨,2009,《经济发展中的最优金融结构理论初探》,《经济研究》第8期,第4~17页。
|
[8] |
林毅夫和龚强,2010,《发展战略与经济制度选择》,《管理世界》第3期,第5~13+187页。
|
[9] |
林毅夫和姜烨,2006,《发展战略、经济结构与银行业结构:来自中国的经验》,《管理世界》第1期,第29~40+171页。
|
[10] |
林毅夫和孙希芳,2003,《经济发展的比较优势战略理论——兼评〈对中国外贸战略与贸易政策的评论〉》,《国际经济评论》第6期,第12~18页。
|
[11] |
林毅夫和孙希芳,2008,《银行业结构与经济增长》,《经济研究》第9期,第31~45页。
|
[12] |
鲁丹和肖华荣,2008,《银行市场竞争结构、信息生产和中小企业融资》,《金融研究》第5期,第107~113页。
|
[13] |
徐飞,2019,《银行信贷与企业创新困境》,《中国工业经济》第1期,第119~136页。
|
[14] |
杨子荣,2019,《企业盈利能力、金融竞争程度与最优金融结构》,《世界经济》第6期,第169~192页。
|
[15] |
于忠和王继翔,2000,《对我国银行业集中度决定因素的实证分析》,《统计研究》第5期,第32~36页。
|
[16] |
余晶晶、何德旭和仝菲菲,2019,《竞争、资本监管与商业银行效率优化——兼论货币政策环境的影响》,《中国工业经济》第8期,第24~41页。
|
[17] |
张杰、郑文平和新夫,2017,《中国的银行管制放松、结构性竞争和企业创新》,《中国工业经济》第10期,第118~136页。
|
[18] |
张捷,2002,《中小企业的关系型借贷与银行组织结构》,《经济研究》第6期,第32~37+54+94页。
|
[19] |
张一林、林毅夫和龚强,2019,《企业规模、银行规模与最优银行业结构——基于新结构经济学的视角》,《管理世界》第4期,第31~47+206页。
|
[20] |
赵旭、蒋振声和周军民,2001,《中国银行业市场结构与绩效实证研究》,《金融研究》第3期,第59~67页。
|
[21] |
Beck, T., R. Levine, and A. Levkov, 2010, “Big Bad Banks? The Winners and Losers from Bank Deregulation in the United States,” Journal of Finance, 65(5):1637~1667.
|
[22] |
Berger, A. N. and L. K. Black, 2011, “Bank Size, Lending Technologies and Small Business Finance,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 35(3):724~735.
|
[23] |
Berger, A. N., N. H. Miller, M. A. Petersen, R. G. Rajan, and J. C. Stein, 2005, “Does Function Follow Organizational Form? Evidence from the Lending Practices of Large and Small Banks,” Journal of Financial Economics, 76(2):237~269.
|
[24] |
Braggion, F., N. Dwarkasing, and L. Moore, 2017, “Nothing Special about Banks: Competition and Bank Lending in Britain, 1885-1925,” Review of Financial Studies, 30(10):3502~3537.
|
[25] |
Breuer, M., K. Hombach, and M. A. Müller, 2018, “How Does Financial Reporting Regulation Affect Firms' Banking?” Review of Financial Studies, 31(4):1265~1297.
|
[26] |
Cerasi, V. and S. Daltung, 2000, “The Optimal Size of a Bank: Costs and Benefits of Diversification”, European Economic Review, 44(9):1701~1726.
|
[27] |
Cetorelli, N. and P. E. Strahan, 2006, “Finance as a Barrier to Entry: Bank Competition and Industry Structure in Local U.S. Markets,” Journal of Finance, 61(1):437~461.
|
[28] |
Cornaggia, J., Y. Mao, X. Tian, and B. Wolfe, 2015, “Does Banking Competition Affect Innovation?” Journal of Financial Economics, 115(1):189~209.
|
[29] |
Diaz-Alejandro, C., 1985, “Good-Bye Financial Repression, Hello Financial Crash,” Journal of Development Economics, 19(1-2):1~24.
|
[30] |
Holmstrom, B. and J. Tirole, 1997, “Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds, and the Real Sector,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(3):663~691.
|
[31] |
Huber, K., 2021, “Are Bigger Banks Better? Firm-Level Evidence from Germany,” Journal of Political Economy, 129(7):2023~2066.
|
[32] |
Liberti, J. M. and M. A. Petersen, 2019, “Information: Hard and Soft,” Review of Corporate Finance Studies, 8(1):1~41.
|
[33] |
Lin, J. Y., X. Sun, and H. X. Wu, 2015, “Banking Structure and Industrial Growth: Evidence from China,” Journal of Banking and Finance, 58:131~143.
|
[34] |
Saidi, F. and D. Streitz, 2021, “Bank Concentration and Product Market Competition,” Review of Financial Studies, 34(10):4999~5035.
|
[35] |
Stein, J. C., 2002, “Information Production and Capital Allocation: Decentralized versus Hierarchical Firms,” Journal of Finance, 57(5):1891~1921.
|
[36] |
Zarutskie, R., 2006, “Evidence on the Effects of Bank Competition on Firm Borrowing and Investment,” Journal of Financial Economics, 81(3):503~537.
|
|
|
|